Research Discussion Paper – RDP 2022-02 The Yield and Market Function Effects of the Reserve Bank of Australia's Bond Purchases
May 2022
1. Introduction
This paper focuses on three Reserve Bank of Australia policy measures that were implemented in the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic and involved purchases of government bonds.[1] In particular, there were: purchases to support government bond market function; purchases to support a yield target for 3-year Australian Government Securities (AGS); and purchases under the bond purchase program designed to lower yields across the yield curve. Our focus is on the extent to which these measures led to lower government bond yields, and also the effect of bond purchases on various measures of government bond market function.
Purchases under the bond purchase program were clearly delineated from other purchases, while the distinction between purchases to support market function and purchases to support the yield target were less clear. For the purposes of this paper we define purchases to support market function as the bonds purchased at auction between 20 March 2020 and 6 May 2020, which consisted of $51.3 billion in purchases of AGS and securities issued by the states and territories (semi-government securities, or semis) with residual maturity between 1 and 10½ years. While these purchases also supported the yield target, and included the yield target bond, their primary focus was to restore good function in government bond markets, which were under considerable strain at the time. We define purchases to support the yield target as the purchases made at auction between 5 August 2020 and 22 October 2021 that were not made under the bond purchase program; they totalled $29 billion, and all were of either the November 2022, April 2023, or April 2024 AGS.[2]
In Section 2 we briefly discuss how central bank government bond purchases can work to ease financial conditions, and review some of the international experience of large-scale bond purchases. This includes both purchases in aid of market function, and purchases designed to lower longer-term yields, commonly known as quantitative easing, or QE. In theory, bond purchases could affect financial conditions when the purchases are announced, when the purchases are implemented, or at both announcement and implementation. We assess both the announcement effects of the Reserve Bank's three measures (Section 3) and the implementation effects – that is, any additional effects that occurred as and when purchases were conducted (Section 4).
For central bank bond purchases announced and conducted during periods when markets are well-functioning, where the amount of future purchases is reasonably predictable, and where the central bank announcement is credible, we would expect most of the effect on yields to occur in anticipation of or at the announcement of the measure, and for there to be relatively little additional implementation effect on yields as purchases are actually made. This follows from the observation that government bond market participants are forward-looking, and so will trade on news regarding future central bank purchases, causing prices to adjust as that news is anticipated or announced.[3]
The above description of the announcement of a credible and predictable purchase amount in a well-functioning market fits well with the Reserve Bank's bond purchase program, which was announced and carried out during a period over which markets were, for the most part, calm. Reflecting this, we find that most of the yield effect of the bond purchase program occurred as market prices adjusted in anticipation of the announcement, and our key results come from an event study covering the period leading up to the announcement. In particular, from September 2020 financial markets were increasingly pricing in the possibility that the Reserve Bank would conduct a bond purchase program focused on longer-term bonds, with these expectations confirmed by the Board announcement on 3 November 2020. We identify the key events that led financial markets to reassess the likelihood that the Reserve Bank would conduct a bond purchase program, and measure the change in government bond yields around these dates. In sum, the yield on the 10-year AGS declined by around 30 basis points. The events include public communications by the Reserve Bank, newspaper articles and market economist reports. In contrast, we find relatively little additional effect on yields from the purchases themselves. For bond purchases to restore market function we find a smaller announcement effect and on balance a larger implementation effect. This is unsurprising as these bond purchases were announced and conducted during a period of market stress, and the amount of purchases was not specified nor predictable at the outset. For the yield target, we find a substantial announcement effect and moderate implementation effects. These findings are discussed in Sections 3 and 4.
In Section 5 we also consider an alternative approach to measuring the effect of the bond purchase program – we construct a counterfactual scenario of what bond yields might have been in the absence of the program. In particular we consider two variants: the first assumes that AGS yields would have moved in line with those of US Treasury bonds; and the second constructs a counterfactual based on the historical relationship between AGS yields and a handful of financial market factors, both domestic and international. The counterfactual scenarios suggest that the bond purchase program reduced yields by somewhere between 20 and 30 basis points, broadly in line with the results from our event study. While longer-term bond yields rose subsequent to the bond purchase program being introduced, this does not imply that the effect of the program was transitory: many other factors influence bond yields, and the evidence suggests that the accumulation of bonds by a central bank holds yields lower than they would have otherwise been over an extended period.[4]
Bond yields can change due to changing expectations of future short-term interest rates or changes in term premia, and in Section 6 we discuss the results of a model that seeks to decompose observed bond yields into these two components. In Section 7 we assess how bond purchases affected government bond market functioning (helping for purchases in support of market function, but hindering, to some degree, for the yield target and bond purchase program). Section 8 concludes.
2. How Bond Purchases Work, and the International Experience
Central bank purchases of longer-term government bonds can lower bond yields via a number of channels including:
- portfolio rebalancing – the accumulation of government bonds by the central bank bids up their price as other assets are only imperfect substitutes, removes interest rate risk from the market, reduces term premia, and induces investors to buy other assets, including to replace the bonds that they sold;[5]
- signalling – bond purchases underline the commitment of the central bank to hold policy rates lower for longer (including because policy rates are unlikely to be raised while bond purchases are ongoing) and so reinforce expectations for a low policy rate;[6] and
- reducing liquidity premia – steady central bank buying reduces the risk of investors being unable to sell bonds at a reasonable price, and increases commercial banks' reserve balances.[7]
The portfolio rebalancing and signalling channels operate in the main via an announcement effect; that is, they cause bond yields to change when bond purchases are announced, rather than when purchases are actually made. For the signalling channel, this is because – assuming the central bank's commitment is credible – signals are delivered with the initial announcement of the program, or subsequent announcements relevant to the total amounts of bonds to be purchased and/or the holding period for those bonds. For the portfolio rebalancing channel, this follows from the fact that market participants are forward-looking, and so will anticipate and trade on the expected effect of future rebalancing flows immediately, as discussed above. Conversely, if the purchase announcement is not perfectly credible, some of the signalling and portfolio rebalancing effect may be delayed until the announcement is actually delivered upon and purchases (and other actions such as reinvestments) are undertaken. The liquidity premia channel relates to the ability to sell bonds in the market without adversely moving yields, and so, to the extent that this is significant, it will have a larger implementation component associated with actual bond purchases as and when they are made (this is especially the case in government bond markets, when liquidity premia are likely to be elevated only in stress conditions). There is no consensus about the relative importance of each channel, but it is generally accepted that the liquidity premia channel is most important during periods of market stress – for example, in March 2020 and the months following – whereas in more normal times, when government bond markets are liquid and well-functioning, liquidity premia are already low and that channel is less important.
The empirical literature on bond purchases, based on experiences in other countries, suggests that at the initial purchase program announcement each 1 per cent of GDP worth of purchases sees yields decline by around 5–7 basis points on average, although the range of estimates is wide.[8] Initial bond purchase programs also tend to have larger apparent effects than the announcement of subsequent programs or extensions of the initial program. This is because additional rounds of bond purchases are often expected by markets and so are at least partially priced in already at the initial announcement of a program, and it is difficult to disentangle these pre-existing expectations from the new information in an announcement of a program extension. Also, many early bond purchase programs were initiated during a period of market stress, when the liquidity premia channel of bond purchases was relatively important, whereas subsequent programs were often implemented in more settled markets when liquidity premia were low. Of note, government bond markets were stable and well-functioning in November 2020 when the Reserve Bank commenced its bond purchase program, whereas this was not the case in early 2020 when the Reserve Bank was purchasing government bonds to restore market function.
The $100 billion of bond purchases announced by the Reserve Bank under the bond purchase program on 3 November 2020 was equivalent to around 5 per cent of nominal GDP in Australia, and so applying the international experience to Australia would suggest a reduction in longer-term yields of around 25–35 basis points. Further, most of the effect would have been expected to have come via the portfolio rebalancing channel lowering term premia: liquidity premia were already low and, while bond purchases would have had some signalling effect, forward guidance and the 3-year yield target were already providing a powerful signal regarding future policy.
3. Event Study of Announcement Effects
As noted, the literature tends to find that in normal markets most of the effect on yields from credible and predictable central bank bond purchase programs occurs when expectations are formed, rather than when purchases are made. For bond purchases that are less credible or predictable, and/or conducted during times of stress and aimed at restoring bond market function, the evidence is more mixed, with a substantial implementation effect from the act of purchasing bonds evident, and a weaker announcement effect as strained markets may fail to immediately incorporate news into bond prices.[9]
This suggests that an event study of the Reserve Bank's bond purchase program – where key dates in the lead-up to and announcement of the program are identified and the yield change that occurs on those dates is assessed – is one way to measure the overall effect of that program. For purchases to support market function and the yield target, it is likely that the announcement effect will only capture part of the overall effect. This is because bond markets were not functioning well when those policies were announced, the quantum of purchases was not readily predictable in advance, and for the yield target perhaps also because of some degree of scepticism among market participants around the Reserve Bank's level of commitment to the program. In this section we consider each policy announcement in turn.
3.1 Purchases to support market function
At midday on 16 March 2020, amid a serious deterioration in financial market function, the Reserve Bank released a statement stating that the Bank ‘stands ready to purchase Australian government bonds in the secondary market to support the smooth functioning of that market’ (RBA 2020a), while on 19 March 2020 at 2.30 pm following an out-of-cycle Board meeting, the Reserve Bank announced a package of policy measures, including its intention to purchase ‘Government bonds and semi-government securities across the yield curve … to address market dislocations’ (RBA 2020b); purchases began the following day.
To assess the effect on AGS yields stemming from these policy announcements, we sum the change in yields over the Australian trading day (8.30 am until 4.30 pm) on 16 and 19 March 2020. As well as examining the change in AGS yields themselves, we also examine the change in the spreads of AGS yields to term-matched overnight indexed swap (OIS) rates.[10] The cash rate target was reduced on 19 March 2020, and a number of other policy measures were announced, all of which were likely to have had an effect on government bond yields. OIS rates provide a measure of market expectations for the evolution of the cash rate, and so can be used as at least a partial control to isolate the effect of the announcement of bond purchases to restore market function, separate from the effects of other policy measures or news released at the same time.[11] For semis, we measure the announcement effect as the change in the spreads of semis yields to AGS yields.
For AGS, we find that the announcement effect varied by term to maturity, with the yields on shorter maturity bonds falling by around 10 basis points in absolute terms (although they would also have been affected by the reduction in the cash rate target and the 3-year yield target, also announced on 19 March 2020), while yields on longer maturity bonds rose by around 10 basis points (Figure 1). Relative to OIS rates, the announcement effect on AGS yields was more pronounced at both ends of the yield curve, with spreads to OIS for the shortest maturity bonds falling by around 20 basis points, while spreads for the longest maturity bonds rose by 20 basis points or more (Figure 2).
For semis, spreads to AGS were little changed on average; that is, semis yields broadly tracked AGS yields over the two policy announcement days (Figure 3).
Taking a longer event window from the open on 16 March 2020 until the close on 20 March 2020 does not change the results for AGS yields or AGS spreads to OIS rates at the short end, although the increases at the long end were larger; for semis, we find that spreads to AGS fell by 5–10 basis points across the yield curve. Conversely, taking a shorter window of just the day of 19 March 2020, the fall in shorter-dated AGS yields was slightly larger, and spreads to OIS for longer-dated AGS did not widen by as much as when using a window of both of the policy announcement days; for semis, the results were little changed.
The lack of a beneficial announcement effect for longer-dated AGS yields and semis spreads is perhaps related to uncertainty by market participants regarding which bonds the Reserve Bank would purchase – while the Reserve Bank's 19 March 2020 statement noted that purchases to support market function would be of bonds across the yield curve, that text came under the rubric of ‘A target for the yield on 3-year Australian Government bonds of around 0.25 per cent’, and some market participants may have assumed that purchases would be concentrated in shorter-dated bonds.[12] Further, the distressed nature of financial markets and strong desire of market participants to raise cash by selling bonds meant that announcements by themselves would not be enough to unclog bond dealers' balance sheets. Rather, that would require actual purchases by the Reserve Bank (Finlay, Seibold and Xiang 2020). In any case, these purchases were not designed to reduce yields, but to restore good market function, which they achieved, as discussed in Section 7 below.
3.2 The yield target
At 2.30 pm on 19 March 2020 the Reserve Bank announced the introduction of a target for the 3-year AGS yield of around 25 basis points, and at the same time announced a reduction in the cash rate target from 50 basis points to 25 basis points. To assess the announcement effect associated with the yield target we consider the change in the yield on the April 2023 AGS – the 3-year AGS at the time – over a 30-minute window following the announcement, as well over the entire day of the announcement. Note that the 3-year yield target provided a form of forward guidance concerning the cash rate, and so attempting to abstract from changes in cash rate expectations by considering the spread of the April 2023 AGS yield to the 3-year OIS rate would be inappropriate, as it would exclude part of the policy's intended effect.[13]
The announcement effect was substantial, at around 25 basis points if measured over a 30-minute event window, or around 15 basis points if measured over the course of the day, although the observed effect is confounded with the reduction in the cash rate target, announced at the same time (Figure 4). However, the effect was insufficient to reduce the 3-year AGS yield all the way to the target; as the Reserve Bank began to implement bond purchases over subsequent days, the yield declined further to become consistent with the target.
3.3 The bond purchase program
The Reserve Bank's bond purchase program was announced at 2.30 pm on 3 November 2020, but there was market speculation leading up to this date that the Bank would announce a QE program. To conduct an event study of the announcement effect we identify nine events in the two months leading up to the initial announcement. We then sum the cumulative change over those dates in AGS yields, the spreads of AGS yields to OIS rates, and the spreads of semis yields to AGS yields.
To identify events, we examine end-of-day market summary reports written by bond traders and market economists over September and October 2020, and select those days where a piece of news was widely cited as relevant to the potential for a Reserve Bank bond purchase program. In total we identify nine such events, which include speeches by Reserve Bank Governor Lowe and Deputy Governor Debelle, the October and November 2020 Reserve Bank Board announcements, three newspaper articles, and two market economist reports (Table 1). We use a one-day interval to measure the change in yields for each event – either ‘open-to-close’ for events that occurred during trading hours, or ‘previous close-to-close’ for events that occurred before the market opened (a two-day event window gives similar results, as does controlling for offshore events by measuring AGS yields as a spread to US Treasury yields).
AGS yields declined across the curve in response to the identified events, with the cumulative change largest at the 10-year point at around 30 basis points (Figure 5). Although the 10-year AGS yield declined for each of the identified events using a one-day window, for a few of the events this masks substantial intraday yield retracements, as markets digested the news associated with the event – our approach thus captures both increases and decreases in expectations for a Reserve Bank bond purchase program, at least on the dates identified. To the extent that we have correctly identified the key dates when market participants reassessed the likelihood of the Reserve Bank conducting a bond purchase program, and no other major news occurred on those dates to move yields for other reasons, this suggests that the bond purchase program led to a fall in the 10-year AGS yield of around 30 basis points.[14]
Date | Event | Change in the 10-year AGS yield |
---|---|---|
14 September 2020* | Newspaper article (‘RBA and markets out of tune’) | −4 bps |
22 September 2020 | Speech by Deputy Governor Debelle | −½ bps |
23 September 2020 | Market economist report calling for further policy easing | −4½ bps |
28 September 2020 | Market economist report calling for further policy easing | −½ bps |
6 October 2020 | October Board announcement | −3½ bps |
7 October 2020* | Newspaper article (‘Odds shortened on more easing’) | −4½ bps |
15 October 2020 | Speech by Governor Lowe | −7½ bps |
26 October 2020* | Newspaper article (‘RBA to buy bonds’) | −5 bps |
3 November 2020 | November Board announcement | −3 bps |
Notes: Yield change measured as ‘open-to-close’ for events that occurred during trading hours, and as ‘previous close-to-close’ for events that occurred outside of trading hours (which are asterisked). In the latter case the date shown is for the next good business day, rather than the date of the event itself. Sources: Authors' calculations; Bloomberg; RBA |
Next, we examine how the spreads of AGS yields relative to OIS rates changed over the event study days. As noted earlier, OIS rates provide a measure of market expectations for the evolution of the cash rate, and so can be used as at least a partial control for any other macroeconomic or financial market news that was unrelated to bond purchases but affected cash rate expectations. This will, however, also ‘control’ for any signalling effect of QE, which will therefore not be captured.[15] The results of this analysis are presented in Figure 6, and show that shorter-dated OIS rates fell by a similar magnitude to AGS yields. This in turn suggests that, for shorter-dated maturities out to around five years, most of the observed fall in AGS yields was due to lower cash rate expectations (or that lower term premia on AGS yields flowed through to lower term premia in OIS rates).[16] For bonds with residual maturity of around 10 years, the fall in the spread of AGS yields to OIS rates is very similar to the fall in actual AGS yields, at around 30 basis points. This suggests that the fall in the 10-year AGS yield was for the most part driven by falls in AGS term and liquidity premia, and most likely the former (because outside of periods of market dysfunction, liquidity premia are typically low in the AGS market).[17]
Additionally, the bond purchase program led to a larger fall in semis yields than in AGS yields, with the spreads of semis yields to AGS yields at the relevant maturities narrowing by around 5 basis points when measured over a one-day event window (Figure 7), and by around 10 basis points when measured over a two-day window.[18] AGS yields act as the benchmark yield curve in Australia, with other fixed income securities typically priced relative to AGS yields or swap rates. If the Reserve Bank had elected to purchase only AGS as part of its bond purchase program, it is likely that semis yields would have fallen by roughly the same amount as AGS yields, leaving the spreads between semis and AGS little changed. The evidence suggests that the inclusion of semis in the program put additional downward pressure on semis yields, resulting in a narrowing in spreads.
While the Reserve Bank announced a $100 billion bond purchase program on 3 November 2020, many market participants were likely to have expected from the outset that further extensions to this program would be announced in time. This implies that the 30 basis point fall in longer-term AGS yields that was observed may be better explained by a larger total expected stock of purchases than the size of the initial announcement. It is hard to be precise about how large the total expected stock of purchases might have been, but it seems reasonable to think that expectations might have been in the order of $200 billion to $300 billion, and later forecasts made by market economists over the first half of 2021 tended to fall within that range. This would imply that each $10 billion (or roughly ½ percentage point of GDP) of expected purchases over the life of the bond purchase program resulted in a fall in longer-term AGS yields of around 1 to 1½ basis points.
Following the initial announcement, two further announcements by the Reserve Bank had relevance for the total expected stock of bond purchases. First, there was the announcement on 2 February 2021 of the first extension to the bond purchase program of a further $100 billion of bond purchases. Second, there was the announcement on 6 July 2021 that, from September, purchases would proceed at a reduced pace of $4 billion per month, down from $5 billion, until at least mid-November 2021. We briefly consider these two subsequent announcements in turn.
A poll by Reuters ahead of the February 2021 Board meeting found that market economists expected the Reserve Bank to announce a further QE program of around $80 billion on average, although the modal expectation was for a $100 billion extension. In the event, the Reserve Bank announced that it would purchase an additional $100 billion of bonds once the original $100 billion of bond purchases was completed in mid-April 2021. AGS yields fell around 1½ basis points in subsequent trading. If one assumes that market economist expectations are representative of wider market expectations as embedded in bond yields, then the $20 billion upward surprise to the total expected stock of bond purchases resulted in a fall in AGS yields of around 1½ basis points, or around ¾ basis points per $10 billion. This is a little lower than the earlier estimate, but given the uncertainties inherent in the estimate it is reasonably close.
On 6 July 2021, the Reserve Bank announced that from early September 2021 it would reduce the pace of bond purchases from $5 billion per week to $4 billion per week, with the new pace to be maintained until at least mid-November 2021. Around half of surveyed market economists had expected the pace of purchases to continue at $5 billion per week and around half had expected a small reduction in the pace. Market economists expected total future purchases to be in the order of $100 billion. If we apply the roughly 10 per cent downward surprise on the pace of purchases to the $100 billion figure for total future purchases, then we arrive at an estimate that the announcement led to a revision lower in the total expected stock of purchases in the order of $10 billion. The yields on AGS eligible to be purchased under the bond purchase program rose by around 2 basis points in the 30 minutes immediately following the 2.30 pm announcement, where they finished the trading day. This change of 2 basis points following a $10 billion surprise is a little larger than the earlier estimate of 1 to 1½ basis points per $10 billion, but again given the uncertainties inherent in the estimate, it is reasonably close.
4. Implementation Effects
In addition to the announcement effects described above, the Reserve Bank's bond purchases may also have lowered yields as and when they occurred. We assess the extent of these possible implementation effects in three main ways:
- First, we examine time-series evidence by using regressions to test whether larger purchases of an individual bond resulted in larger yield changes on the day of the purchases (or over subsequent days).[19] For purchases to support market function and purchases under the bond purchase program, we use the same functional form for our regression, as the way in which these purchases were conducted was similar, even if the aims were different. For purchases under the yield target we adapt the regression slightly to better suit the context for those purchases.
- Second, we perform a similar time-series analysis, but use inclusion or exclusion in a purchase operation as the key explanatory variable, rather than the purchase amount. We only consider purchases to support market function and purchases under the bond purchase program, as the concept of inclusion or exclusion is less relevant for yield target purchases.
- Third, we look at the cross-sectional evidence over the course of a program to see whether bond lines that were more heavily purchased by the Reserve Bank saw larger changes in yields that persisted for some time after the purchases were made. Again, we only consider purchases to support market function and purchases under the bond purchase program.
We do not examine directly the related question of whether the flow of new bond issuance leads to higher yields as and when it occurs, though new issuance indirectly enters our analysis by adding to the outstanding stock of bonds.
4.1 Time-series evidence using purchase amounts
4.1.1 Market function purchases and the bond purchase program
Following the approach of De Santis and Holm-Hadulla (2020), we use the time series of bond yields to measure the effect of bond purchases on those yields. In particular, we estimate the equation:
where yit denotes, for bond i, the day t change in yield (for AGS) or spread to AGS (for semis); purchasesit denotes the amount of bond i purchased on day t relative to the remaining free float of bond i (that is, purchases of bond i divided by the outstanding stock of bond i not already held by the Reserve Bank); purchases _ adjacentit denotes the amount of bonds within one year's residual maturity of bond i purchased on day t relative to the remaining free float of bond i (that is, purchases of bonds within one year's residual maturity of bond i divided by the outstanding stock of bond i not already held by the Reserve Bank); and bi and vt are bond and time fixed effects.
We estimate this equation via ordinary least squares (OLS), and also via instrumental variables (IV) where we use a dummy variable indicating those bonds excluded from a given auction either because they had recently been issued or tapped by the issuing authority, or because they were not within the target purchase range, to instrument for purchasesit. For purchases _ adjacentit we instrument using the share of bonds with residual maturity within one year of bond i that are excluded because they have recently been issued or tapped by the issuing authority.[20] These instruments are both relevant – a bond cannot be purchased if it is not included in a given auction – and exogenous.
IV would be the more appropriate estimation method to employ if, within an auction, the amount of each bond purchased by the Reserve Bank depended on the level of, or changes in, the yield on that bond over the day in question. However, the Reserve Bank did not adjust its purchases in this way: within a given auction, the purchase amount of each bond was determined based on the relative attractiveness of offers to sell that bond, where attractiveness was assessed using the offered yield relative to prevailing mid-market rates. It is possible that counterparties adjusted the attractiveness of their offers to sell different bonds based on yield levels or changes, although any desire on the part of dealers to sell more or less of any individual bond should already have been reflected in the market price of that bond, so it is not clear that this would be the case. For these reasons, we prefer the OLS estimates, but for completeness also provide IV estimates.
Results are shown in Table 2. For AGS purchases in aid of market functioning, purchasing 1 percentage point of the free float of a bond reduces its yield and the yield on adjacent bonds by around ¼ basis points on average, although there is considerable noise in the data and these results are not statistically significant. For AGS purchases under the bond purchase program, the yield effects are smaller but statistically significant, at around 0.1 to 0.2 basis points. For semis, we find that purchases in aid of market function reduce spreads to AGS by between 0.1 and 0.5 basis points, depending on the estimation method, while purchases of adjacent bonds have no effect. For semis purchases under the bond purchase program, the effects are smaller, at around 0.1 basis points for direct purchases and again no effect for purchases of adjacent bonds. Overall, we tend to find larger effects when one would expect liquidity premia to be relatively high.
Market functioning purchases | Bond purchase program | |||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
AGS yields | Semis spreads | AGS yields | Semis spreads | |||||||||
OLS | IV | OLS | IV | OLS | IV | OLS | IV | |||||
Purchases of the eligible bond | −0.34 (0.25) |
−0.27 (0.37) |
−0.14*** (0.04) |
−0.48*** (0.14) |
−0.11** (0.04) |
−0.22*** (0.08) |
−0.08** (0.03) |
−0.14** (0.06) |
||||
Purchases of its adjacent bonds | −0.20 (0.15) |
−0.25 (0.16) |
−0.01 (0.01) |
0.08 (0.06) |
−0.10*** (0.02) |
−0.17*** (0.03) |
0.00 (0.00) |
−0.02 (0.02) |
||||
Fixed effects | Bond and time fixed effects for all regressions | |||||||||||
No of obs | 448 | 448 | 1,696 | 1,696 | 5,234 | 5,234 | 13,372 | 13,372 | ||||
Adjusted R2 | 0.56 | 0.56 | 0.54 | 0.50 | 0.89 | 0.89 | 0.29 | 0.28 | ||||
Notes: Heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation corrected (HAC) standard errors in parentheses; *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 per cent levels, respectively. Yields and spreads in basis points. For market functioning purchases, the sample is from 20 March 2020 to 6 May 2020; for the bond purchase program, it is from 5 November 2020 to 10 February 2022. Bonds issued by Tasmania and the two territories are excluded. Adjacent bonds are those that mature within one year of the eligible bond. An F-test on the instrument equation rejects the null of weak instruments at the 1 per cent level for all models, while the Wu-Hausman test fails to reject the null that OLS is consistent for the AGS market function model and the semis bond purchase program model, but rejects the null for the other models.
Sources: Austraclear; Australian Office of Financial Management; Authors' calculations; RBA; Yieldbroker |
4.1.2 The yield target
The yield on the 3-year AGS rose above target on occasion. One method that the Reserve Bank used to achieve the yield target was to purchase the target bond, and also AGS with residual maturity close to that of the target bond. From March to May 2020 such purchases were aimed at both supporting government bond market function and the yield target, while from August 2020 until October 2021 they were conducted in support of the yield target alone. Accordingly, we will look at only these later purchases.
The Reserve Bank conducted purchases in support of the yield target a total of 18 times between August 2020 and October 2021, buying a total of $29 billion across the November 2022, April 2023 and April 2024 AGS (Figure 8). On average, the yields on the target bonds fell by around 1 basis point on days when they were purchased by the Reserve Bank and were little changed on other days (Figure 9). The Reserve Bank's ownership shares of these bond lines increased to 8, 39 and 63 per cent of the outstanding amounts for the 2022, 2023 and 2024 bonds respectively, from 7, 10 and 5 per cent at the start of August 2020.
However, the average change does not account for differences in the size of the Reserve Bank's purchases, or other potentially relevant factors such as changes in expectations for the cash rate. To assess more accurately the impact of the Reserve Bank's purchases, we estimate a regression that includes the size of the purchases, as well as the 3-month OIS rate and the 10-year AGS yield (Table 3).[21] Overall, we find that purchasing $1 billion of the target bond reduced the yield on that bond by 1 basis point. Using the share of free float purchased rather than the dollar value as the explanatory variable, we find that purchasing 1 percentage point of the free float reduced the yield by 0.2 basis points. Purchases were therefore effective in achieving the yield target, although the measured effect of purchases on the yield is estimated to have dissipated over time.
Purchases in $b | Purchases as a share of free float of target bond | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Target bond yields | 3-year OIS rate | Target bond yields | 3-year OIS rate | ||
Purchases of target bond | −1.02*** (0.24) |
0.60 (0.48) |
−0.22*** (0.03) |
0.14 (0.09) |
|
Purchases of adjacent bond | −0.44 (0.27) |
0.44 (0.56) |
−0.12* (0.06) |
0.16 (0.16) |
|
Change in 3-month OIS rate | 0.76** (0.36) |
1.12*** (0.19) |
0.77** (0.36) |
1.11*** (0.18) |
|
Change in 10-year AGS yield | 0.31** (0.15) |
0.36*** (0.08) |
0.31** (0.15) |
0.36*** (0.09) |
|
No of obs | 630 | 315 | 630 | 315 | |
Adjusted R2 | 0.22 | 0.23 | 0.22 | 0.24 | |
Notes: HAC standard errors in parentheses; *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 per cent levels, respectively. Yields and rates in basis points.
Sources: Australian Office of Financial Management; Authors' calculations; Fenics; RBA; Yieldbroker |
By contrast, a regression of daily changes in the 3-year OIS rate on similar factors indicates that purchases of the target bond were associated with increases in the 3-year OIS rate on average, although the moves were not statistically significant.[22] This suggests that, although the Reserve Bank tended to purchase bonds in response to sustained increases in market participants' expectations for the cash rate (when the increases were reflected in the yield on the 3-year AGS), the Reserve Bank's purchases did not – on their own, on the days of the purchases – dampen participants' cash rate expectations. This is consistent with the flow of Reserve Bank purchases being interpreted narrowly by the market as an operational tool for achieving the yield target on the relevant AGS, rather than as a new signal about the Board's future monetary policy decisions. See also Lucca and Wright (2022) for a discussion of the yield target and the effect of yield target bond purchases.
The announcements by the Reserve Bank of bond purchases to support the yield target typically contained an element of news for market participants, perhaps in part because participants were still learning about the Reserve Bank's reaction function for the use of this new tool. On days when such purchases were announced, the yield on the 3-year AGS tended to fall immediately after the announcement; by contrast, announcements of the Reserve Bank's regular and predictable purchases under the bond purchase program elicited negligible immediate market reaction (Figure 10). For the 3-year AGS, the element of news was consistent with the aim of the policy being to keep the yield on the target bond ‘around’ a certain level, rather than exactly at a certain level. Hence, participants could not predict whether the Reserve Bank would intervene on any particular day. It was also consistent with the Reserve Bank retaining operational flexibility in its purchases, rather than committing to a strict rule or pattern for these purchases.
4.2 Time-series evidence using inclusion and exclusion dummies
We estimate a dummy variable regression similar to that in Section 4.1.1, where we model the change in yield (for AGS) or spread to AGS (for semis) on a variable indicating whether a bond was included in an auction (i.e. eligible for purchase), and additionally control for the effect of each bond line and day (this is similar to performing an analysis of variance to test whether, on auction days, bonds that were in the auction saw statistically different yield changes from bonds that were not in the auction; see Fisher (1925)). Similar to the IV regressions discussed previously, taking the eligibility of a bond to be purchased in an auction as a ‘treatment’ (and ignoring how much of each bond is actually purchased) has the advantage of using only variables that we know to be exogenous as regressors.
As background, AGS purchases under the bond purchase program were conducted on Mondays and Thursdays, with Mondays for bonds with residual maturity of around 5 to 7 years, and Thursdays for bonds with residual maturity of around 7 to 10 years. Semis auctions under the bond purchase program were conducted on Wednesdays, and initially alternated between shorter-dated and longer-dated bonds on a fortnightly basis, before these auctions were combined in March 2021 into a single auction spanning all eligible bonds. Considering shorter-dated and longer-dated auctions separately, we find that eligibility within auctions has no statistically significant impact on the change in yield or spread (Table 4).
AGS yields | Semis spreads | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Short-dated | Long-dated | Short-dated | Long-dated | Combined | ||
Bond eligible for purchase | −0.11 (0.14) |
−0.02 (0.07) |
0.41 (0.27) |
0.37 (0.24) |
0.02 (0.08) |
|
Fixed effects | Bond and time | Bond and time | Bond and time | Bond and time | Bind and time | |
No of obs | 495 | 486 | 148 | 179 | 1,877 | |
Adjusted R2 | 0.94 | 0.99 | 0.54 | 0.37 | 0.40 | |
Notes: Heteroskedasticity corrected (HC) standard errors in parentheses; *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 per cent levels, respectively. Yields and spreads in basis points. The sample is purchase days from 5 November 2020 to 10 February 2022. Combined semis auctions replaced the short- and long-dated auctions from 24 March 2021. Bonds issued by Tasmania and the two territories are excluded. Sources: Authors' calculations; RBA; Yieldbroker |
Alternatively, we can consider the shorter-dated and longer-dated groupings of bonds together, such that for each auction the non-eligible bonds consist of not only those bonds within the relevant maturity grouping that were excluded due to being recently tapped or issued, but also all bonds from the other maturity grouping (which were also not eligible to be purchased). Using this approach, we find that purchases under the bond purchase program lowered AGS yields by 0.6 basis points on the day, and lowered semis spreads by 0.2 basis points on the day (Table 5).[23] These results, combined with those above, suggest that purchases in one segment of the yield curve affect yields and spreads in that part of the yield curve relative to other parts of the yield curve, even if they do not affect relative yields and spreads within that segment of the yield curve. The effect is short-lived, however, and dissipates after a few days (Figure 11). For bond purchases in support of market function, we find that an AGS being eligible to be purchased reduced its yield by 1.1 basis points, relative to other AGS not eligible to be purchased, while for semis, eligibility resulted in a 0.6 basis point reduction in spread to AGS (Table 5). Similar to purchases under the bond purchase program, the effect is short-lived and dissipates after a few days.
Market functioning purchases | Bond purchase program | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
AGS yields | Semis spreads | AGS yields | Semis spreads | ||
Bond eligible for purchase | −1.12** (0.52) |
−0.64*** (0.17) |
−0.57*** (0.07) |
−0.17*** (0.05) |
|
Fixed effects | Bond and time | Bond and time | Bond and time | Bond and time | |
No of obs | 448 | 1,696 | 5,234 | 13,372 | |
Adjusted R2 | 0.56 | 0.54 | 0.89 | 0.29 | |
Notes: HAC standard errors in parentheses; *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 per cent levels, respectively. Yields and spreads in basis points. For market functioning purchases, the sample is from 20 March 2020 to 6 May 2020; for the bond purchase program, it is from 5 November 2020 to 10 February 2022. Bonds issued by Tasmania and the two territories are excluded.
Sources: Authors' calculations; RBA; Yieldbroker |
4.3 Cross-sectional evidence
Finally, following the approach of D′Amico and King (2013), we use variation in the share of individual bond lines that were purchased over the course of a program to examine whether the purchase of a larger share of bonds resulted in larger yield changes that were persistent. In particular, for AGS we estimate the equation:
where yi denotes the change in yield on bond i from the day before purchases began until 6 May 2020 for purchases to restore market function, or 10 February 2022 for purchases under the bond purchase program; purchasesi denotes the share of free float of bond i that the Reserve Bank purchased; purchases _ adjacenti denotes the share of free float of bonds with residual maturity within one year of bond i that the Reserve Bank purchased; mi denotes the residual maturity of bond i; denotes the squared residual maturity of bond i; and ci denotes the coupon of bond i.[24] For semis, we estimate a similar equation, where yi instead denotes the change in spread to AGS of bond i, and an additional term denoting issuer fixed effects is included.
We estimate this equation via OLS, also via IV where we use inclusion in a bond futures basket (of both bond i and also the share of bonds within one year's residual maturity of bond i ); the share of bonds held by the Reserve Bank just prior to the program commencement (of both bond i and also bonds within one year's residual maturity of bond i ); and yield curve fitting errors just prior to the program commencement, to instrument for purchasesi and purchases _ adjacenti.[25] These instruments are clearly exogenous, being determined before any purchases took place, and are relevant to the extent that Reserve Bank purchases are correlated with pricing anomalies (captured by yield curve fitting errors), previous ownership levels, and/or the liquidity of each bond line (captured by inclusion in a futures basket).[26]
We consider IV in case of any possible endogeneity between the yield change that we observe and the share of bonds purchased (this could occur, for example, if the Reserve Bank purchased bonds in part due to their higher yield, although as noted earlier this was not the case). As earlier, we prefer the OLS estimates (and cannot reject that they are consistent), but provide IV estimates for completeness.
For purchases in support of market function, we find that purchasing 1 percentage point of the free float of an AGS reduced the yield on that bond by 0.7 to 0.8 basis points, while purchases of adjacent bonds resulted in a fall in yield of 1.2 to 1.5 basis points; for semis, there was little to no additional impact on the spread to AGS for purchases of the bond itself or adjacent bonds (Table 6). For the bond purchase program, we find no statistically significant effect of purchases on AGS yields or semis spreads.
Market functioning purchases | Bond purchase program | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
AGS yields | Semis spreads | AGS yields | Semis spreads | ||||||||
OLS | IV | OLS | IV | OLS | IV | OLS | IV | ||||
Purchases of the eligible bond | −0.82*** (0.16) |
−0.69*** (0.16) |
−0.12 (0.11) |
0.38 (0.41) |
0.17 (0.12) |
0.20 (0.14) |
0.02 (0.04) |
0.00 (0.09) |
|||
Purchase of its adjacent bonds | −1.54*** (0.36) |
−1.21*** (0.27) |
0.18 (0.12) |
1.00 (0.66) |
0.26 (0.21) |
0.22 (0.27) |
−0.01 (0.03) |
−0.06 (0.08) |
|||
Residual maturity (years) | 9.35*** (1.57) |
6.63** (2.23) |
−7.08*** (1.14) |
−2.89 (3.22) |
11.08*** (3.19) |
11.35*** (3.23) |
5.51*** (0.96) |
6.03*** (2.00) |
|||
Residual years2 (years2) | −1.55*** (0.15) |
−1.31*** (0.20) |
0.61*** (0.10) |
0.21 (0.26) |
−0.96*** (0.25) |
−0.98*** (0.25) |
−0.46*** (0.07) |
−0.49*** (0.17) |
|||
Coupon rate (per cent) | −0.40 (0.37) |
−0.13 (0.67) |
0.33 (0.54) |
0.84 (0.88) |
0.84 (0.94) |
0.88 (0.99) |
1.02*** (0.33) |
0.85* (0.44) |
|||
Fixed effects | None | None | Issuer | Issuer | None | None | Issuer | Issuer | |||
No of obs | 14 | 12 | 53 | 37 | 16 | 16 | 36 | 31 | |||
Adjusted R2 | 0.98 | 0.98 | 0.56 | 0.22 | 0.72 | 0.72 | 0.67 | 0.51 | |||
Notes: HC standard errors in parentheses; *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 per cent levels, respectively. Yields and spreads in basis points. For market functioning purchases, the start and end dates are 19 March 2020 and 6 May 2020; for the bond purchase program, they are 4 November 2020 and 10 February 2022. Bonds issued by Tasmania and the two territories are excluded, and the bond purchase program regressions only include bonds that were included in the program from the start. An F-test on the instrument equation rejects the null of weak instruments for the market function AGS model but not the other IV models, while the Wu Hausman test fails to reject the null that OLS is consistent for all IV models.
Sources: Austraclear; Australian Office of Financial Management; Authors' calculations; Bloomberg; RBA; Yieldbroker |
4.4 Summary
To summarise, our results suggest that the implementation effect for purchases under the bond purchase program was, at most, small and temporary. This conclusion can be supported by examining how the yields on AGS and semis just outside the purchase range evolved relative to the yields of AGS and semis just inside the purchase range. The difference in yields between these sets of non-purchased and purchased bonds did not steadily increase for either AGS or semis, as one might have expected if the implementation effect was strong and persistent, but rather tended to follow changes in the equivalent difference in OIS rates (which should have been largely unaffected by any implementation effect associated with bond purchases; Figure 12).
For purchases in support of market function and purchases in support of the yield target, the estimated implementation effects are on balance larger. The first finding is broadly consistent with the international literature on bond purchases, with the impact of purchases as and when they are made being more important during periods of market stress. The second finding is consistent with yield target purchases containing an element of news as market participants learned about the Reserve Bank's reaction function – that is, its commitment to this objective.
5. Additional Analysis of Yield Effects
In addition to the announcement of the yield target and purchases of the target bond, other Reserve Bank actions in support of the yield target had an effect on the target bond yield. In particular, in early March 2021 the April 2024 AGS yield had risen above the target and liaison suggested that a number of market participants had positioned to profit from the Reserve Bank discontinuing the yield target in the near future, by borrowing the target bond under repo and selling it outright (that is, short-selling the bond). At 12.30 pm on 9 March 2021 the Reserve Bank communicated to market participants that it had increased the fee that it was going to charge counterparties to borrow the target bond from 25 to 100 basis points, which made short-selling the bond more costly, while at 9 am on 10 March 2021 Governor Lowe gave a speech in which he reaffirmed the Reserve Bank's commitment to the yield target (Lowe 2021). The increase in the stock lending fee saw the April 2024 AGS yield fall by around 2 basis points on announcement, while Governor Lowe's speech saw the yield open a further 1 basis point lower the next day, and continue to fall over the course of the week (Figure 13). See also RBA (2021) for a further discussion of these events.
The stock lending fee for the target bond was changed two further times, with similarly large impacts on the target bond yield. The stock lending fee was decreased from 100 basis points to 25 basis points, announced around 12.30 pm on 7 May 2021 following a sharp fall in the April 2024 AGS yield to a level below the target. This saw the yield move around 2 basis points higher (Figure 13). An increase in the stock lending fee at 4.30 pm on 19 October 2021 back to 100 basis points saw the yield fall from around 17 basis points to around 11 basis points. The standard deviation of daily changes for the 3-year AGS yield is a little less than 1 basis point, so the relatively large moves in the yield following the stock lending fee changes and Governor Lowe's speech, in the absence of any other news of note, suggests that these actions had a meaningful effect on the target bond yield. A higher stock lending fee makes bond market intermediation more costly, and this is discussed further in Section 7.
Turning to the bond purchase program, to complement our main results we construct a counterfactual scenario for how AGS yields might have moved in its absence. We then take the difference between the observed yield change and this counterfactual as another measure of the impact of the program.
A simple counterfactual is to assume that, in the absence of bond purchases by the Reserve Bank, longer-term AGS yields would have moved in line with the government bond yields of the United States. This approach makes a few assumptions. In particular, it assumes that AGS yields tend to move with US Treasury yields in response to global news events (but not necessarily news pertaining to a change in the relative economic prospects or stance of monetary policy in each country). Another assumption is that the main news on relative monetary policy stances over the period in question related to domestic bond purchase expectations.
Focusing on the spread between 10-year yields for AGS and US Treasury bonds, after rising at the onset of the COVID-19 crisis as the relative outlook for US growth and inflation deteriorated rapidly, the spread remained stable at around 25 to 30 basis points through to mid-2020 (Figure 14). However, this spread narrowed over September and October 2020 as market participants began to price-in the likelihood of bond purchases in Australia, with the spread reaching around zero when the Reserve Bank's bond purchase program was announced in early November. To the extent that the evolution of longer-term US Treasury yields provides a good counterfactual for what would have happened to longer-term AGS yields in the absence of a bond purchase program, this approach suggests that the announcement of the bond purchase program led to a fall in longer-term AGS yields of around 30 basis points. With the exception of relatively short-lived moves higher in early and late 2021 associated with global increases in bond yields, the spread remained close to zero for an extended period, suggesting that the announcement effect was persistent but that there was no additional implementation effect that depressed Australian yields further as and when bond purchases were made. However, over time the accumulation of other market moving events and differing outcomes for the Australian and US economies lessens the validity of this comparison, and we would not expect the spread to remain near zero indefinitely.
A slightly more sophisticated approach is to construct a model of AGS yields that controls for a handful of domestic and international factors, but for the most part does not capture the effects of the Reserve Bank's bond purchase program, and then use the implied path of AGS yields resulting from this model as a counterfactual against which to measure the yield impact of the program.[27] The model we employ attempts to explain monthly changes in the 10-year AGS yield using: changes in the 10-year Australian OIS rate; changes in the 10-year US Treasury yield; changes in US Federal Reserve bond holdings as a share of US GDP; and changes in the spread between the 3-month BBSW and the 3-month Australian OIS rate. As noted earlier, the 10-year OIS rate will capture market expectations for the cash rate path, and therefore any signalling effect of bond purchases. This implies that our measure will abstract from any such signalling effect, so the measure should be taken as a lower bound rather than a central estimate. Regarding the other explanatory variables: the US Treasury yield captures international factors affecting long-term interest rates; US Federal Reserve bond holdings capture the yield impact of bond purchases in the United States (with market expectations for bond holdings, which were estimated using survey data, used instead of actual holdings starting from May 2020); and the BBSW–OIS spread is a measure of domestic risk aversion and a proxy for the cost of funding holdings of AGS in the repo market. Overall, the counterfactual 10-year AGS yield implied by the model, in the absence of bond purchases, is up to around 20 basis points higher than the observed 10-year AGS yield around the announcement of the bond purchase program, with much of the difference persisting for an extended period (Figure 15).
Model results are given in Table 7.[28]
Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | Preferred model | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Includes 3-month USD LIBOR–OIS spread |
Includes Reserve Bank bond holdings to Australian GDP |
Includes 10-year US Treasury yield–OIS spread |
||
10-year AUD OIS rate | 0.79*** (0.12) |
0.81*** (0.12) |
0.81*** (0.12) |
0.77*** (0.09) |
10-year US Treasury yield | 0.22*** (0.08) |
0.21*** (0.07) |
0.20*** (0.07) |
0.22*** (0.06) |
10-year US Treasury yield–OIS spread | 0.34 (0.43) |
0.37 (0.43) |
0.35 (0.43) |
|
Reserve Bank bond holdings to GDP | 0.01 (0.07) |
0.04 (0.06) |
||
US Federal Reserve bond holdings to GDP | 0.04** (0.02) |
0.03*** (0.01) |
0.04*** (0.01) |
0.04*** (0.01) |
3-month BBSW–OIS spread | 0.18* (0.11) |
0.19* (0.10) |
0.20** (0.10) |
0.16 (0.10) |
3-month USD LIBOR–OIS spread | 0.02 (0.03) |
|||
No of obs | 32 | 32 | 32 | 32 |
Adjusted R2 | 0.94 | 0.94 | 0.94 | 0.94 |
Durbin-Watson statistic | 2.29 | 2.36 | 2.43 | 2.48 |
Notes: HAC standard errors in parentheses; *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 per cent levels, respectively. Estimated zero-coupon yields were used for AGS and US Treasury yields throughout the models. Sources: Authors' calculations; Bloomberg; Federal Reserve Bank of New York; RBA; Yieldbroker |
6. Expected Future Short-term Rates and Term Premia
So far we have focused on estimating the effect of the Reserve Bank's bond purchases on the overall level of government bond yields. Bond yields can also be thought of as having two distinct components: the average short-term interest rate that is expected to prevail over the life of the bond (i.e. the expected return from investing in a series of short-term government notes over the coming ten years); and the term premium that investors demand for holding a long-term bond rather than investing in a series of shorter-term investments. Changes in expectations for future short-term interest rates give information on bond investors' expectations of policy rates over coming years, while changes in term premia give information on the levels of interest rate risk and inflation risk that investors perceive, among other things, as well as their attitudes to these risks. We would expect a bond purchase program to push down on term premia via the portfolio rebalancing channel, while the effect on investors' expectations for future short-term interest rates is less clear: future short-term rate expectations could be lowered via the signalling channel if bond purchases were taken as a signal that policy rates would be held lower for longer than previously expected; or future short-term rate expectations could actually increase if bond purchases now were seen as supporting the economy and bringing forward the day when a higher policy rate was needed.
One cannot observe expected future short-term rates or term premia directly by looking at bond yields, since bond yields reflect the combination of both. One can, however, estimate these quantities using a model. A model that is often used for this purpose is a so-called affine term structure model, which assumes that expectations and term premia (and therefore yields) are driven by a few unobserved factors. By estimating those factors, and the model parameters, one can recover estimates of expectations and term premia. It is important to note, however, that a number of assumptions must be made to estimate an affine term structure model, some of which may not hold, and so model outputs should be taken as indicative only.
We use the model of Hambur and Finlay (2018) to estimate expected future short-term interest rates and term premia.[29] Figure 16 shows that the 10-year nominal bond yield fell over the first few months of 2020 and reached a low in March of that year, as fears around the health and economic impact of COVID-19 grew. The 10-year yield stayed in a relatively narrow range over the remainder of 2020, before increasing in early 2021 alongside increasing optimism regarding the economic outlook. Underlying these movements, however, are divergent trends in estimates of expectations for future short-term rates and term premia. In particular, the onset of the crisis saw expectations of average future short-term rates fall substantially, before rebounding in early 2021. The term premium, in contrast, rose as the crisis intensified, but then fell over the remainder of 2020. These outcomes align with what might have been expected: as the crisis intensified, investors began to expect that the Reserve Bank would hold policy rates low for many years into the future. At the same time, the amount of risk in the economy was clearly increasing, and investors' desire to bear that risk was declining, leading to higher term premia. But as governments and central banks responded to the crisis, and as effective vaccines were developed, investors became more optimistic about future prospects and so raised their expectations for average future short-term interest rates. At the same time the Reserve Bank undertook substantial purchases of government bonds, the perceived riskiness of holding bonds fell, and investors' appetite to bear risk increased, pushing down on term premia.[30]
One can decompose the three nominal time series presented in Figure 16 further, with each composed of a real component and an inflation-compensation component. That is, expectations for average future nominal short-term rates can be thought of as comprising expectations for average future real (i.e. inflation-adjusted) short-term rates plus expectations for average future inflation, and similarly for term premia. These decompositions are shown in Figures 17 and 18, and suggest that the fall and then increase in nominal short-term interest rate expectations was largely driven by moves in real rate expectations, which were likely to have been related to lower real growth expectations initially, which then recovered. Meanwhile, changes in inflation expectations were similar in direction but more muted. It was also a sharp move higher in real term premia in early 2020 that drove nominal term premia higher, while the inflation risk premium initially fell as the perceived probability of high future inflation declined.[31] Higher real term premia reflected uncertainty around future real interest rates, in turn driven by uncertainty around economic growth, while lower inflation risk premia reflected less concern around the risk of high future inflation.[32] These moves were then reversed over the rest of 2020 and into 2021.
7. Effects on Market Functioning
Finally, we examine how bond purchases by the Reserve Bank affected the functioning of government bond markets. The international experience suggests that central bank purchases can support good bond market function and lower liquidity premia, particularly in times of market stress. This was in fact the aim of purchases by the Reserve Bank in support of market function. However, the Reserve Bank buying a large share of outstanding government bonds could, in principle, have negative effects on Australia's government bond markets. For example, if the Reserve Bank were to buy so much of a certain bond line that it became scarce, bond dealers may become reluctant to offer to sell that bond to their clients for fear that they would be left short. This could result in reduced bond market liquidity, and could see bid-offer spreads widen and pricing anomalies emerge. Eventually, this could impair related instruments such as bond futures contracts (which are used by banks and corporations to hedge interest rate risk), it could diminish the attractiveness of government bond markets for investors, and could contribute to larger liquidity premia for government bonds in Australia (e.g. Han and Seneviratne 2018; Blix Grimaldi, Crosta and Zhang 2021).
For bonds purchased with the aim of supporting market function, there was no sign of harm. Rather, the evidence suggests that these purchases achieved their aim: bid-offer spreads and yield curve fitting errors, both of which spiked dramatically higher in early March 2020, fell as purchases proceeded (Figures 19 and 20).[33] Conversely, there is evidence that the Reserve Bank's substantial holdings of the April 2023 and April 2024 AGS – purchased in support of the yield target – resulted in some deterioration in market function around the 3-year part of the yield curve. For example, bid-offer spreads remained very low for longer-term AGS and for semis over the second half of 2020 and through 2021, but rose to be higher than usual for shorter-term AGS, spiking in particular for the April 2024 AGS around the discontinuation of the yield target (Figure 19). Yield curve fitting errors for bonds purchased under the bond purchase program also remained within their historical range over the second half of 2020 and most of 2021, although rose for semis alongside a sharp global increase in yields in early 2021, and rose for AGS alongside an increase in global yields and the discontinuation of the yield target in late 2021 (Figure 20).
Indicators of bond futures market function suggest a similar story: the period over which purchases to support bond market function were undertaken saw mispricing between bonds and futures narrow, after having risen substantially around the onset of the pandemic, and saw more futures contracts available to trade at the best available price (Figure 21). Conversely, these measures deteriorated over 2021, particularly for the 3-year futures contract, and particularly around periods of market volatility (including early 2021 and ahead of November 2021 when the yield target was discontinued). Market contacts noted the perceived risk of the Reserve Bank discontinuing the yield target at various points through 2021, which would have seen the 3-year futures price gap lower, as well as the Reserve Bank's substantial holdings of 3-year bonds (and an associated fall in liquidity which made hedging futures against bonds more difficult), as contributing to the deterioration in futures market function, although other factors including uncertainty associated with the rapidly changing economic outlook may also have contributed.
To formally test the effect of the Reserve Bank's bond purchases on bid-offer spreads, we estimate the equation:
where yit denotes the average bid-offer spread for bond i in week t; purchasesit denotes the share of remaining free float of bond i purchased in week t (that is, purchases in the week divided by the outstanding stock not already held by the Reserve Bank at the beginning of the week); holdingsit denotes the share of the total stock of bond i held by the Reserve Bank at the beginning of week t; and bi and vt are bond and time fixed effects.
We estimate this equation for AGS and semis purchased in support of market functioning and under the bond purchase program (using issuer fixed effects instead of bond fixed effects in the case of semis), and also estimate a similar equation for purchases in support of the yield target, but in this case dropping time fixed effects in favour of a dummy to denote weeks in which the stock lending fee charged for borrowing April 2023 AGS and April 2024 AGS from the Reserve Bank was elevated. Results are presented in Table 8.
Market functioning purchases | Bond purchase program | Yield target purchases | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
AGS | Semis | AGS | Semis | |||
Purchases of free float in the week | −1.61*** (0.36) |
−3.28** (1.48) |
0.23* (0.12) |
−1.57 (1.30) |
0.44*** (0.01) |
|
Holdings of total stock at the start of the week | −0.53 (0.33) |
−2.00* (1.10) |
0.18*** (0.07) |
−0.67 (0.49) |
0.53*** (0.01) |
|
Dummy for elevated stock lending fee | 2.89*** (0.24) |
|||||
Fixed effects | Bond and time | Issuer and time | Bond and time | Issuer and time | Bond | |
No of obs | 112 | 425 | 1,098 | 2,802 | 132 | |
Adjusted R2 | 0.81 | 0.66 | 0.78 | 0.03 | 0.23 | |
Notes: HAC standard errors in parentheses; *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 per cent levels, respectively. For market functioning purchases, the sample is from 20 March 2020 to 6 May 2020; for the bond purchase program, it is from 5 November 2020 to 10 February 2022; for yield target purchases, it is from 5 August 2020 to 2 November 2021. Bonds issued by Tasmania and the two territories are excluded. Sources: Austraclear; Australian Office of Financial Management; Authors' calculations; RBA; Yieldbroker |
We find that purchases in support of market function led to lower bid-offer spreads, as intended. In particular, for each 10 percentage points of the free float of an AGS purchased to support market function, the bid-offer spread of that bond narrowed by 1.6 basis points, while for semis the effect was larger at 3.3 basis points. Additionally, a 10 percentage point higher share of the outstanding stock of a semis bond line by the Reserve Bank was associated with the bid-offer spread on that bond being 2 basis points narrower, perhaps because higher Reserve Bank holdings during the period of market dysfunction in early 2020 were associated with less of a supply overhang on dealer balance sheets for those bond lines.
For the bond purchase program and yield target, however, we find that AGS purchases led to wider bid-offer spreads. For AGS purchased under the bond purchase program, each 10 percentage points of purchases of the free float was associated with bid-offer spreads being 0.2 basis points wider, and similarly each 10 percentage points of holdings of the outstanding stock was associated with bid-offer spreads being 0.2 basis points wider. For AGS purchased to support the yield target, each 10 percentage points of purchases was associated with bid-offer spreads being 0.4 basis points wider, while each 10 percentage points of bond holdings was associated with bid-offer spreads being 0.5 basis points wider. We also find that an elevated stock lending fee led to higher bid-offer spreads, which is unsurprising as a higher fee makes intermediation by bond dealers more costly.[34]
For semis purchased under the bond purchase program, there was no statistically significant effect of purchases on bid-offer spreads. Taken together, the results above suggest that in the already liquid AGS market, the Reserve Bank removing bonds from the market outside of periods of stress can lead to a rise in bid-offer spreads as bonds become more difficult to source. Conversely, for the less liquid semis market, the existence of a regular buyer in the form of the Reserve Bank offsets any negative impact from less bonds being available to the wider market.
We also replicate the above analysis for turnover in place of bid-offer spreads, with yit instead denoting the log of the average turnover in bond i in week t, using turnover data for trades processed through the Yieldbroker platform. Although these trades represent only a part of trading activity for AGS and semis, our results will be informative if the sample is representative of trading in the wider market. Results are presented in Table 9. For market function purchases and purchases under the bond purchase program, we find no statistically significant effect of purchases or holdings on turnover. For yield target purchases, by contrast, we find that turnover increases significantly in weeks when the Reserve Bank makes purchases, but that higher Reserve Bank holdings ultimately result in less secondary market turnover.
Market functioning purchases | Bond purchase program | Yield target purchases | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
AGS | Semis | AGS | Semis | |||
Purchases of free float in the week | 0.13 (0.43) |
0.90 (0.67) |
−0.03 (0.25) |
0.32 (0.60) |
0.93*** (0.27) |
|
Holdings of total stock at the start of the week | 0.10 (0.36) |
−0.52 (0.37) |
−0.08 (0.11) |
−0.03 (0.11) |
−0.27*** (0.07) |
|
Dummy for elevated stock lending fee | 0.17 (0.42) |
|||||
Fixed effects | Bond and time | Issuer and time | Bond and time | Issuer and time | Bond | |
No of obs | 112 | 384 | 1,098 | 2,639 | 132 | |
Adjusted R2 | 0.28 | 0.35 | 0.39 | 0.19 | 0.09 | |
Notes: HAC standard errors in parentheses; *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 per cent levels, respectively. For market functioning purchases, the sample is from 20 March 2020 to 6 May 2020; for the bond purchase program, it is from 5 November 2020 to 10 February 2022; for yield target purchases, it is from 5 August 2020 to 2 November 2021. Bonds issued by Tasmania and the two territories are excluded. Sources: Austraclear; Australian Office of Financial Management; Authors' calculations; RBA; Yieldbroker |
Finally, by regressing the log change in the weekly average number of 3-year futures contracts available to trade at the best price on weekly yield target purchases, we find that each 10 percentage points of purchases of the free float across either the April 2023 or April 2024 bond is associated with a 36 per cent fall in the number of futures contracts available to trade, significant at the 1 per cent level. Similarly, regressing average weekly mispricing between 3-year bonds and 3-year futures on weekly yield target purchases, yield target bond holdings and the stock lending fee suggests that each 10 percentage points of bond purchases is associated with a 0.4 basis point increase in bond-futures mispricing, while an elevated stock lending fee is associated with a 1 basis point increase in bond-futures mispricing, both significant at the 1 per cent level.[35]
8. Conclusion
In this paper we assess the effect of three Reserve Bank policy measures involving government bond purchases: purchases in support of government bond market function conducted between March and May 2020; purchases in support of the yield target conducted from August 2020 until October 2021, and purchases aimed at lowering longer-term yields conducted under the bond purchase program from November 2020 until February 2022.
We find that the announcement of purchases in support of market function saw a reduction in the yields on shorter-dated AGS of 10 to 20 basis points, but that there was no decline in longer-dated AGS yields or in the spreads of semis yields to AGS. The actual purchases had an additional yield effect, with each percentage point of the free float of AGS purchased estimated to have reduced yields by up to around 1½ basis points, and each percentage point of the free float of semis purchased estimated to have reduced semis spreads by up to around ½ basis point. These purchases were not designed to lower yields, however. Rather, they were designed to support market function, and the evidence suggests that they achieved this: bid-offer spreads fell as purchases proceeded, and various measures of futures market function improved.
For the yield target, we find a significant announcement effect on the 3-year AGS yield, in the order of 15 to 25 basis points. However, the policy announcement was not enough by itself to keep the 3-year yield consistently at the target, especially given how uncertain and rapidly changing the economic outlook was over the period. Occasional bond purchases were required to reinforce the target. Purchases did have an effect on yields, of around 1 basis point per $1 billion purchased, or 0.2 basis points per percentage point of free float purchased, although this effect appeared to dissipate over time. Yield target purchases led to wider bid-offer spreads and are likely to have contributed to some reduction in the functioning in the 3-year futures contract for a time.
Our best estimate is that the bond purchase program reduced longer-term AGS yields by around 30 basis points leading up to and on the announcement of the program, while the additional implementation effect from purchases appears to have been be small and temporary. Purchases under the program were associated with a small widening in bid-offer spreads.
References
Arrata W and B Nguyen (2017), ‘Price Impact of Bond Supply Shocks: Evidence from the Eurosystem's Asset Purchase Program’, Banque de France Working Paper 623.
Bailey A, J Bridges, R Harrison, J Jones and A Mankodi (2020), ‘The Central Bank Balance Sheet as a Policy Tool: Past, Present and Future’, Paper prepared for the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Policy Symposium on ‘Navigating the Decade Ahead: Implications for Monetary Policy’, Jackson Hole, 27–28 August. Available at <https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/-/media/boe/files/paper/2020/the-central-bank-balance-sheet-as-a-policy-tool-past-present-and-future.pdf?la=en&h>.
Bank of England's Independent Evaluation Office (2021), ‘IEO Evaluation of the Bank of England's Approach to Quantitative Easing’, January. Available at <https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/independent-evaluation-office/ieo-report-january-2021/ieo-evaluation-of-the-bank-of-englands-approach-to-quantitative-easing>.
Blix Grimaldi M, A Crosta and D Zhang (2021), ‘The Liquidity of the Government Bond Market – What Impact Does Quantitative Easing Have? Evidence from Sweden’, Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No 402.
CGFS (Committee on the Global Financial System) (2019), Unconventional Monetary Policy Tools: A Cross-Country Analysis, CGFS Papers No 63, Bank for International Settlements, Basel.
Christensen JHE and S Krogstrup (2019), ‘Transmission of Quantitative Easing: The Role of Central Bank Reserves’, The Economic Journal, 129(617), pp 249–272.
D′Amico S and T King (2013), ‘Flow and Stock Effects of Large-Scale Treasury Purchases: Evidence on the Importance of Local Supply’, Journal of Financial Economics, 108(2), pp 425–448.
De Santis RA and F Holm-Hadulla (2020), ‘Flow Effects of Central Bank Asset Purchases on Sovereign Bond Prices: Evidence from a Natural Experiment’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 52(6), pp 1467–1491.
Debelle G (2021), ‘Monetary Policy during COVID’, Shann Memorial Lecture, Online, 6 May.
Eser F, W Lemke, K Nyholm, S Radde and AL Vladu (2019), ‘Tracing the Impact of the ECB's Asset Purchase Programme on the Yield Curve’, European Central Bank Working Paper Series No 2293.
Finlay R, C Seibold and M Xiang (2020), ‘Government Bond Market Functioning and COVID-19’, RBA Bulletin, September.
Fisher RA (1925), Statistical Methods for Research Workers, Oliver and Boyd, Edinburgh. Internet resource available at <http://psychclassics.yorku.ca/Fisher/Methods/>.
Gagnon JE (2016), ‘Quantitative Easing: An Underappreciated Success’, Peterson Institute for International Economics Policy Brief No PB16-4.
Gorodnichenko Y and W Ray (2017), ‘The Effects of Quantitative Easing: Taking a Cue from Treasury Auctions’, NBER Working Paper 24122, rev March 2018.
Hambur J and R Finlay (2018), ‘Affine Endeavour: Estimating a Joint Model of the Nominal and Real Term Structures of Interest Rates in Australia’, RBA Research Discussion Paper No 2018-02.
Han F and D Seneviratne (2018), ‘Scarcity Effects of Quantitative Easing on Market Liquidity: Evidence from the Japanese Government Bond Market’, IMF Working Paper No WP/18/96.
Ihrig J, E Klee, C Li, M Wei and J Kachovec (2018), ‘Expectations about the Federal Reserve's Balance Sheet and the Term Structure of Interest Rates’, International Journal of Central Banking, 14(2), pp 341–390.
Kawamoto T, T Nakazawa, Y Kishaba, K Matsumura and J Nakajima (2021), ‘Estimating Effects of Expansionary Monetary Policy since the Introduction of Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing (QQE) Using the Macroeconomic Model (Q-JEM)’, Bank of Japan Working Paper Series No 21-E-4.
Krishnamurthy A and A Vissing-Jorgensen (2012), ‘The Aggregate Demand for Treasury Debt’, Journal of Political Economy, 120(2), pp 233–267.
Li C and M Wei (2013), ‘Term Structure Modeling with Supply Factors and the Federal Reserve's Large-Scale Asset Purchase Programs’, International Journal of Central Banking, 9(1), pp 3–39.
Lowe P (2021), ‘The Recovery, Investment and Monetary Policy’, Keynote address to the AFR Business Summit, Sydney, 10 March.
Lucca DO and JH Wright (2022), ‘The Narrow Channel of Quantitative Easing: Evidence from YCC Down Under’, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No 1013.
RBA (Reserve Bank of Australia) (2020a), ‘Statement by Philip Lowe, Governor’, Media Release No 2020-07, 16 March.
RBA (2020b), ‘Statement by Philip Lowe, Governor: Monetary Policy Decision’, Media Release No 2020-08, 19 March.
RBA (2020c), Statement on Monetary Policy,November.
RBA (2021), Statement on Monetary Policy, May.
Schnabel I (2021), ‘Asset Purchases: From Crisis to Recovery’, Keynote speech at the Annual Economic Conference of Latvijas Banka on ‘Sustainable Economy in Times of Change’, Online, 20 September.
Vayanos D and J-L Vila (2021), ‘A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates’, Econometrica, 89(1), pp 77–112.
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank Matthew Boge, Andrea Brischetto, Christopher Kent, Marion Kohler, Carl Schwartz, John Simon, Matthew Wheadon and participants in internal Reserve Bank seminars for helpful comments and suggestions. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Reserve Bank of Australia. The authors are solely responsible for any errors.
Footnotes
See Debelle (2021) for a discussion of all of the Reserve Bank's policy measures during the pandemic. [1]
From its inception on 19 March 2020 until 6 July 2021, the yield target was for the ‘3-year AGS’, specified in terms of the AGS with residual maturity closest to three years, being the April 2023 AGS until 20 October 2020, and the April 2024 AGS thereafter. From 6 July 2021 until it was discontinued on 2 November 2021, the yield target shifted from applying to the 3-year AGS – which changes over time – to applying specifically to the April 2024 AGS. The level of the yield target was changed once, in line with a change in the cash rate target, being around 25 basis points between 19 March 2020 and 3 November 2020, and around 10 basis points from 4 November 2020 until 2 November 2021. The bond purchase program was initiated at the November 2020 Board meeting when $100 billion of purchases were announced, with an 80/20 split between AGS and semis. In February 2021, the Board extended the program by announcing the purchase of an additional $100 billion of bonds after the completion of the initial purchases in mid-April 2021. In July and September 2021, the Board further extended the program, to the effect that purchases would proceed at a pace of $4 billion per week until at least mid-February 2022. The bond purchase program ended on 10 February 2022. Overall, the Reserve Bank purchased $40.3 billion of AGS and $11.1 billion of semis ($51.3 billion in total) to support market function between 20 March 2020 and 6 May 2020; $29 billion of AGS to support the yield target between 5 August 2020 and 22 October 2021; and $223.7 billion of AGS and $57.0 billion of semis ($280.7 billion in total) under the bond purchase program between 5 November 2020 and 10 February 2022. Purchases under each measure are detailed in Statistical Table A3 ‘Monetary Policy Operations’ – see <https://www.rba.gov.au/statistics/tables/xls/a03.xls>. [2]
A thought experiment is useful in affirming this: imagine that a central bank could credibly commit to a set amount of bond purchases, and no more, and then implemented this policy. If yields responded to the flow of these purchases, rather than the announced stock, yields would fall when the central bank commenced purchasing bonds but then spring back as soon as purchases stopped. But such a predictable course of events would present a large arbitrage opportunity to bond traders, who would exploit and therefore remove it. See also D′Amico and King (2013), Arrata and Nguyen (2017) and De Santis and Holm-Hadulla (2020). [3]
Here we are referring to the portfolio rebalancing effect of bond purchases, discussed in Section 2; the liquidity effect is related to the flow of bond purchases and so is likely to exist only while purchases are being conducted, while the signalling effect will be affected by any future signals from the central bank. See, for example, Ihrig et al (2018) and Eser et al (2019) for further discussion. [4]
Portfolio rebalancing flows will tend to be strongest for assets that are most similar to those purchased, and be weaker for assets that are less similar (Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen 2012). For example, if the central bank wishes to purchase a large volume of 10-year government bonds, it will need to induce those currently holding those bonds, and who may highly value their liquidity and safety, for example, to sell and purchase other assets instead. A small fall in the yield of 10-year government bonds relative to other very similar assets (e.g. 9- or 11-year government bonds) may be enough to induce investors to rebalance their portfolios to such substitutable assets, thereby spreading the price impact of central bank buying to those assets. Conversely, government bond yields are likely to have to fall more significantly in order to induce an investor to instead buy corporate bonds, or equities, which have quite different characteristics to government bonds. See also Li and Wei (2013), Gorodnichenko and Ray (2017) and Vayanos and Vila (2021) for models in which preferred habitats play an important role in the portfolio rebalancing channel. [5]
See also Schnabel (2021) and the references therein for a discussion of how the signalling channel might operate. [6]
See also Christensen and Krogstrup (2019) for a discussion of the role of central bank reserves. [7]
See, for example, Gagnon (2016), CGFS (2019), Bailey et al (2020) and Bank of England's Independent Evaluation Office (2021) for review papers. [8]
See, for example, Bailey et al (2020) and the references therein, as well as Ihrig et al (2018) and Eser et al (2019). [9]
OIS are a fixed-for-floating interest rate swap, where one party agrees to pay a market-determined fixed interest rate (the ‘OIS rate’) in exchange for receiving a floating interest rate based on the realised daily overnight cash rate, and the other party agrees to take the other side of those cash flows. Abstracting from the existence of various types of risk premia, which may bias the OIS rate up or down, the fixed OIS rate can be interpreted as a market measure of the expected average overnight cash rate over the term of the OIS contract. [10]
OIS rates will also be influenced by bond purchases, so measuring the announcement effect of purchases as the change in the spreads of AGS yields to OIS rates will tend to understate the impact. Note also that, in Australia, long-dated OIS rates are priced based on the prevailing rates on two other types of financial instruments: standard fixed-for-floating interest rate swaps and BBSW–OIS basis swaps, both of which are liquid out to ten or more years into the future. In a standard fixed-for-floating interest rate swap, one party receives a fixed interest rate (the ‘swap rate’) in exchange for paying a floating 3- or 6-month bank bill swap rate (BBSW). In a BBSW–OIS basis swap, a party pays the floating 3- or 6-month BBSW, and receives a floating rate that is linked to the realised cash rate. By entering both of these swaps, an investor can engineer an exposure where they receive a fixed rate and pay a floating rate linked to the realised daily overnight cash rate, which is what an OIS contract delivers. [11]
See the text associated with the second numbered item in RBA (2020b). The yield on the 10-year AGS rose from 1.5 per cent immediately prior to the 2.30 pm Board announcement on 19 March 2020 to 1.9 per cent immediately after. It traded between 1.6 and 1.9 per cent over the following half-hour in very strained conditions, before falling back to 1.5 per cent over the rest of the afternoon. The yield had been around 1 per cent two days prior, and was 0.9 per cent two days later. [12]
On the day, the 3-year OIS rate fell from around 30 basis points pre-announcement to a little below 25 basis points by the end of the day, that is, it closed in line with the Bank's forward guidance (Figure 4). [13]
By comparison, if we consider the four months preceding the 3 November 2020 announcement, excluding those dates identified in our event study, and sum random samples of nine daily changes in the 10-year AGS yield selected from that period, we find a mean yield change of +3 basis points and that 95 per cent of the samples had a yield change of between –7 and +25 basis points, suggesting that our event study result is statistically significant. [14]
OIS rates also contain term and other premia, which will be somewhat affected by government bond purchases. [15]
Of these two interpretations, the first interpretation appears the most likely, including because the Reserve Bank also lowered the cash rate target and the target for the yield on the 3-year Australian Government bond from 25 basis points to 10 basis points at the November 2020 Board meeting. [16]
In fact, the expected impact of bond purchases on longer-term policy rate expectations is ambiguous. On the one hand, bond purchases serve to underline the central bank's commitment to keep policy rates low for a long period. But conversely, to the extent that bond purchases are effective in boosting economic activity and inflation, they should bring forward the day when the policy rate needs to be increased. [17]
Semis are less liquid than AGS, and so measuring yield changes over a slightly longer window may be appropriate. [18]
Note that under the bond purchase program, the amount of purchases of any individual bond was determined by the relative attractiveness of offers to sell that bond, compared with other bonds also eligible to be purchased. That is, the Reserve Bank did not set purchase amounts for individual bonds. See below for further discussion. [19]
The Reserve Bank offered to purchase different sets of bonds on alternating days, and excluded recently tapped or issued bonds from its bond auctions – see ‘Reserve Bank Purchases of Government Securities’, 3 November 2020, available at <https://www.rba.gov.au/mkt-operations/announcements/rba-purchases-of-government-securities-2020-11.html>. [20]
Note that while only one bond was the target bond for the purpose of the yield target at any particular time, we consider the yields on both the April 2023 AGS and the April 2024 AGS throughout our analysis. This is for three reasons: both of these bonds were at some point the target bond; even prior to the April 2024 AGS becoming the target bond, the Reserve Bank made some purchases of the April 2024 AGS to smooth the transition between target bonds; and even after the April 2024 AGS became the target bond, the Reserve Bank made some purchases of the April 2023 AGS in order to reinforce the forward guidance associated with the yield target. See RBA (2020c) for further details. [21]
It is likely that any causation is going in the other direction, with higher 3-year OIS rates associated with higher 3-year AGS yields and therefore with the Reserve Bank deciding to conduct yield target purchases. [22]
Note that the regression results presented in Table 2 of Section 4.1.1 also included both auction buckets. [23]
Some authors such as D′Amico and King (2013) estimate a regression similar to the above, but use the change in price as the variable of interest, rather than the change in yield. We do not do this as the Reserve Bank's explicit aim under the bond purchase program was to lower bond yields, rather than raise bond prices (even if the two concepts are closely related). Changes in bond prices are also more likely to be mechanically affected by the coupon and term to maturity of each bond than are changes in yield. [24]
For semis, the futures basket instruments are not used (because bond futures contracts refer to AGS only). For AGS purchased to support market function, the pre-commencement holdings instruments are not used (because the Reserve Bank held none of the AGS purchased prior to the commencement of the program). [25]
Bonds included in a bond futures basket tend to be more liquid and actively traded than otherwise similar bonds, while yield curve fitting errors can be used as an indication of bond mispricing. [26]
See Kawamoto et al (2021) for a similar exercise focused on Japan. Ideally, we would prefer to construct a model of AGS yields that accurately captures the channels of a bond purchase program discussed earlier, and then use this model to directly measure the impact of bond purchases on yields. The relatively short time horizon over which the Reserve Bank has been conducting bond purchases, however, means that any such model would be poorly estimated. Further, and as discussed earlier, market participants' expectations of bond purchases are an important determinant of yields, and we do not have an accurate measure of these expectations through time for Australia. Together, these difficulties make estimating a model of yields that directly captures the effect of bond purchases unviable in the current context. [27]
Modelling the spread between 10-year AGS and US Treasury yields, and/or including additional explanatory variables (such as Reserve Bank bond holdings, the 10-year US OIS rate and the 3-month USD LIBOR–OIS spread) produced similar results. The additional explanatory variables that we tested were not statistically (or economically) significant in most specifications, so we did not include them in our preferred model. Although the 3-month BBSW–OIS spread fell short of statistical significance in some specifications, we have included it in our preferred model as we consider it likely that the spread had some influence on the 10-year AGS yield in the sample period. [28]
The model separates expectations from term premia using the time-series properties of the estimated factors (which are assumed to evolve according to the distribution under which expectations are formed) and also survey data on economists' cash rate and inflation expectations (which do not contain term premia). [29]
Term premia are also estimated to have been quite low (and sometimes negative) in the years preceding the pandemic, and earlier bond purchase programs by other central banks are likely to have contributed to this. [30]
Part of the fall in our estimate of the inflation risk premium (and part of its subsequent reversal, at least initially) is better attributed to the deterioration (and subsequent recovery) in the function of government bond markets, the prices of which underpin our estimate. However, the continued increase in the inflation risk premium from the second half of 2020 is less attributable to this, because by that time government bond markets were again functioning fairly well. [31]
Movements in the equivalent 3-year rates and premia are qualitatively similar, although the nominal 3-year term premium rose more sharply over 2021, driven mainly by a move higher in the inflation risk premium; the expected 3-year real rate was more negative over 2020 and 2021 at around –1½ per cent; and the increase in expected inflation from the low in March 2020 was more pronounced. [32]
See also Finlay et al (2020) for further discussion of these measures of market function, and for a broader discussion of how bond purchases by the Reserve Bank supported government bond market function over early 2020. [33]
As discussed earlier, however, increasing the stock lending fee tended to lower the 3-year AGS yield, thereby obviating the need for additional bond purchases, which would have reduced the free float of bonds and increased bid-offer spreads. [34]
Note that we use a log differences specification for the first regression as the number of futures contracts available to trade appears to be non-stationary, while we use a levels specification for the bond-futures mispricing regression as that variable is stationary. Note also that we control for predictable intra-quarter variation, due to the futures expiry cycle, in both regressions. We do not attempt similar regressions for purchases to support market function or purchases under the bond purchase program, as those programs had much less week-to-week variation in purchases, making identification of any effect more difficult. [35]