Transcript of Question & Answer Session The Future System for Monetary Policy Implementation
Swati Pandey (Bloomberg)
Thank you, Chris. That was a very detailed speech, and I think its going to be a document that
market participants will continue to refer to in the weeks and months to come because how central
banks react to this huge liquidity has been a question that everybody has been trying to understand
and, like you said, a lot of these things are still untested as well. Im going to start off
with some questions and then Ill open to the floor. The first question … youre
talking about moderating the balance sheet size: do we have an idea of how large this is going to be,
and by when? Its a two-part question.
Christopher Kent
No, we dont, is the short answer. What it will depend on is banks underlying demand for
reserves and, as I suggested in my speech, that may have changed. In the past, they were really used
to operating with very small total reserves in the system. Something in the order of $2 billion
to $3 billion was a daily outcome for the banking system. Now that theyve got used to a
much larger balance, they might have changed their operations more persistently. Thats
something that theyll learn and its something that the system will have to deal with. But
the point is having open market operations with full allotment. What that means is that the banks
tell us how much they want at the fixed price; as long as theyve got good collateral,
theyll get that amount. That means that the supply of reserves—in other words, the size of our
balance sheet—will be determined by that demand. We know that its less than where we are now.
We can come up with some rough estimates and the banks can do their own, but we dont know
exactly where it will be. We know were there when more of the banks start to show up at our
auctions. At the moment, the demand, as I showed in my chart, is fairly low; when that starts to pick
up, we know that were getting close.
Swati Pandey
So that is once the system kicks in, like, some months after the system kicks in.
Christopher Kent
Well, the system is all ready to go and its just a matter of transitioning. As our bonds mature
and as the TFF gets repaid, the reserves will naturally come down and well get to a point where
the banks say, Ah, I dont have as many reserves as I would like just sitting in my
account; Im going to need to go to the Reserve Bank and get some from their auctions. So,
when that happens, thats when we think well know that were transitioning from
excess to something thats ample.
Swati Pandey
Right, okay. The system is largely untested globally as well, right? Like, you mentioned ECB, BoE and
Riksbank, they have also introduced it, but then there is no history. What risks do you see with this
system?
Christopher Kent
I think this is going to be the best system for Australia and I dont envisage significant
risks. Theres always some risk, particularly during a transition. I think the reason Im
fairly confident here that the transition will be relatively smooth is because we already have these
open market operations at full allotment working. That started, actually, quite a bit earlier in an
informal sense. I think it was the Friday, 16 March 2020, when we knew that there were a lot of
stresses in the financial system. So we increased at our auctions, which werent full allotment;
we said, Well provide more trying to calm markets down. Then banks came to us and
asked for way more than that total, and we said, Okay, you can have it. So we started
early on in that process of this concept of a full allotment auction; you get what you need. But
weve now got a fixed price. Weve been doing this for some years and the banks dont
have hesitation in showing up, if they need it. So we dont have a stigma about banks coming to
that main facility and, because of that, were confident that theyll just show up when
they need it, and that should smooth the transition.
Swati Pandey
Right. When you talk about the tools for liquidity management, you have mentioned forex swaps and
bonds. Do we have an idea of the mix yet? How do we know that youre not doing Stealth
QE in the market?
Christopher Kent
Well, Ill come back to the Stealth QE comment. But the mix we dont know.
Thats something that well be thinking carefully about in the period ahead. I think a
really important consideration, as I kept mentioning, is our footprint in markets depending on what
the demand is, the underlying demand. If we were to satisfy all of that just through open market
operation repos, that would imply quite a large footprint potentially in those markets, and that
might crowd out private sector repo activity, which we dont want to do. Given that, it might
make sense to also underpin the supply with some other tools. FX swaps is one, and you can do that in
a way that has minimal interest rate risk. We used to hold a portfolio of bonds as well, and we could
hold some of them in bonds; as long as theyre fairly short-dated, they wont impose much
interest rate risk on the RBA. So, its balancing that footprint across the different markets
and thinking about the risk for the RBA balance sheet itself. So thats something to be
determined.
Swati Pandey
And Stealth QE.
Christopher Kent
Stealth QE. I wouldnt call it Stealth QE at all. People never called it
that in the past when we did it. I think the big difference here is that this is to satisfy an
operational need. Its at the very short end of the market. Were not holding it with the
intention of trying to influence rates, particularly further out the curve, and theres no big
announcement during a period of trauma in the financial system or the economy. So its holding
some bonds; we used to do that. It might be in a slightly higher quantity than in the past—that
remains to be seen—but its at the short end of the market; whereas QE is kind of out the curve,
trying to influence longer term rates and expectations about those rates.
Swati Pandey
Right. Your balance sheet size peaked in March 2022 and, since then, we have seen $100 billion
going away and then, through the rest of this year, well see another $100 billion of TFF
unwind and two of the bonds—the April 2024 and November 2024 bonds—mature as well. Youve said
that this particular framework does not have implications for monetary policy but, with this
$100 billion moving out of the financial system, do you see any monetary policy
implications?
Christopher Kent
No. Its happening because of an unwinding of the earlier unconventional policies, but I
dont think that unwinding, particularly with this system, will have implications for pressures
and rates in money markets and, therefore, very little to do with financial conditions. The unwinding
of the earlier policies—QT itself—is having some effect, some very marginal effect; its pretty
small. Ive described in the past that QT is, by design, about as fun as watching paint dry. So
its designed to have very gentle effects. Thats quite different from QE, where markets
are under considerable stress and there are a lot of pressures, and banks are coming in and
were making a big announcement to say, Were doing a whole series of things,
including this, in order to help calm markets and bring longer rates down. This is just letting
the bonds roll off nice and slowly. Thats whats happening here and around world, and I
dont think its having implications for our financial conditions in a significant
manner.
Swati Pandey
Okay. Sticking with monetary policy, if you have just one word to describe the RBAs current
monetary policy stance, what is that one word? Neutral, tightening or easing? There are three
options.
Christopher Kent
I would refuse to answer a question based on such a limitation. Economists cant just use one
word.
Swati Pandey
Okay, you can have more than one word.
Christopher Kent
Look, the path is uncertain, so maybe uncertain is kind of the key thing. Weve said
that the outlook is uncertain. Inflation has come down and its moderating, and thats a
good thing; its still high, so theres more work to be done. But demand is weakening, and
demand and supply are coming into better balance. Thats what you need in order to see a further
moderation in inflation. The central forecasts have that, and they also have a further easing in the
tightness in labour market conditions. But none of thats certain, and there are things that
could move in either direction. Given that—given that the interest rate path is uncertain—the Board
made the point, quite pointedly, as Michele has said many times, the Governor, were not ruling
anything in or anything out with regards to rates.
Question
Thanks for that speech this morning. I want to ask about active bond sales; have there been any
updates? Noting that Deputy Governor Andrew Hauser has been in the role for about six
weeks … has Andrew come into the role with perhaps some fresh thinking around bond sales,
and have there been any developments on that front?
Christopher Kent
Nothing that I can refer you to. Weve said that the current approach is to let them mature but,
periodically, come back to consider that case. So, when we do, well let you know. Thats a
decision of the whole Board and there are a number of different considerations to think about. But,
again—I think I also said this recently—just like the current approach to the bonds maturing being
about as interesting as watching paint dry; active QT, if the Board were to pursue it, would be, by
design, about as fun as watching paint dry but maybe with the window cracked open, but not much more
fun than that.
Question
You mentioned on the graph several times foreign reserves. You noted that the FX market
had come under some stress in 2020, and yet it feels like the RBA has not focused at all on
intervention in currency markets as going some way to alleviating the pressure on monetary policy
and, for that matter, to reducing the amount of liabilities required. It looked to me on the graph
that our foreign assets increased during a time of currency stress. Why has the RBA effectively
forgotten about the FX market? That is question 1. Question 2: if the reason is that you dont
think you have any control in the FX market, what, other than 2020, are our foreign reserves for?
Should we just get rid of all of our foreign reserves—if were just saying the superannuation
section buys so many offshore assets every month that we cant do anything about the Aussie
dollar being lower than it otherwise could be, hence we are importing inflation—or, lastly, should we
just hire some more people in the FX section of the RBA?
Christopher Kent
I would disagree with your characterisation of the FX market during the pandemic, particularly with
regard to the Aussie dollar. It was one market that was actually working relatively well through that
period compared to government bond markets, which were not, so we didnt see a need for
intervention. There were some pressures elsewhere and, in order that those pressures didnt
build, central banks together, with the Fed sort of leading the way, provided the option for
US dollar swaps to help alleviate that pressure. So we provided an auction where banks could bid
for US dollars that would have been provided, through us, through the Fed. Demand was extremely
low, showing that there were very limited pressures here, very limited needs for Aussie banks to
obtain US dollars. So I would argue that the markets at that stage were not under a lot of
pressure. But thats not to say that it couldnt happen in the future, in which case
reserves would be potentially useful to alleviate those sorts of pressures, but I didnt see
them at that time.
Question continued
Can I just have a quick follow-up? Im not talking about the mechanics of the market; Im
talking about the fact that the RBA appears to no longer consider that foreign exchange intervention,
testing and smoothing have any role to play at all, and a hundred per cent of the heavy lifting
of the RBA is on monetary policy. Why didnt the RBA buy spot Aussie?
Christopher Kent
I just disagree with your characterisation. I dont think our purchases or otherwise of Aussie
would have affected the level of the Aussie dollar in a way that would allow you to not raise
interest rates as much. Indeed, you can look at the Bank of Japan: the exchange rate is really being
dominated by moves in interest rate differentials. I think thats true of the Australian economy
as well, but thank you.
Question
I have just two questions. If you go back to 2008, world credit markets were closing and there was a
real crisis. Since then, weve got through that and weve got through the pandemic. Do you
think, given the sophistication of central banks—the lessons theyve learnt and the level of
sophistication in policy—we can be confident that we wont have another sort of world liquidity
crisis perhaps more of the 2008 variety than the 2020? Secondly, if the two Board view of
the current government goes ahead, how do you think the new Monetary Policy Board might operate; and
could you have a situation where some of the people are very experienced economists and might have
their own very different views on some of the technicalities that youve outlined? It might be a
more perhaps interventionist board or a board with more-aggressive opinions.
Christopher Kent
In terms of the lessons, particularly from the GFC, I think you cannot rule out stresses that come
from some external source impacting economies and, therefore, financial markets. I think whats
important though is what do central banks and other policymakers do in response to that? Very much
with the GFC in our mind, when banks were hoarding liquidity back in mid-March 2020 because of the
pandemic and the uncertainties, and not just here but globally, we took those lessons from the GFC
and, well before the Board had convened and made those announcements about the package on
20 March—I think it was on the Friday before that or it could have been the Thursday, or I could
be mistaken—we just said, Right, were here to provide liquidity to the banks;
theyve got plenty of collateral, and what theyre looking for is liquidity, and we
set up these auctions. We increased the amount that we were willing to provide. Then the banks all
said, We need more than that, and there and then—right there and then—I remember standing
next to Guy Debelle, in front of the screen, saying, Right, were just going to trade
right through this; were just going to provide the banks with the liquidity that they
need. Thats how our system is designed. Now, that calmed markets for a few days. Then
there was our package, and then there was the governments response and all these other things
happening offshore, including what other central banks did; and what you otherwise might have had is
a financial crisis, a la the GFC, but that was curtailed very quickly. So I think thats the
lesson: do what you need to do; your job is to provide liquidity to solvent banks with good
collateral; do it. Our system now is pretty much how thats going to be designed. I wont
speculate on the monetary policy committee. Its still in front parliament and is still to be
decided, and we dont know who the members are. So Ill let that one pass through, but
thanks for the question.
Question
Chris, taking a little longer perspective and injecting a bit of macro into the thinking around this,
one consideration, I guess, has been that theres been a long-run decline in the real neutral
interest rate and so, therefore, theres a greater likelihood that at any point in time, when
you need to cut because of an impending recession or whatever, youre going to hit the lower
bound. I think thats been seen as a consideration for not going back to a corridor system
because, if you hit the lower bound and you have to do QE, a corridor system is going to be
ineffective, so its better to have a system thats more resilient. So how has the thinking
around that been part of the Boards consideration; and how do you think the ample reserve
system will work, when we do at some point hit the lower bound and theres, presumably, some
need for QE or something like that?
Christopher Kent
Well, on the need for QE, I wont say much more than that we did that review internally and
published that on QE. I think the conclusion is that it wouldnt be the first thing youd
do, but you certainly wouldnt rule it out. I think thats in keeping with, actually, what
happened post pandemic. It wasnt one of the first things that we did; it was one of the later
things because, for the Australian economy, we didnt think it would be quite as effective. We
thought it would still have some effect, so the Board pursued it later in 2020, but they pursued
other things first. So I think, depending on the circumstances, there are other tools—unconventional,
if you like. They might have implications for the balance sheet and I think, very much, an ample
system would be sort of more resilient to that. Youd still say that youre in the same
system, even under those stresses; youd just be increasing the supply of reserves. You might
want to also increase the supply from other sources, whether its FX swaps or short-term
government bond holdings. That was actually the first thing that started early. We started that also
before the March 20 announcement of the package; we started saying, These bond markets are
dysfunctional; were going to come in and buy some bonds to alleviate some of those
stresses. Again, that would not be consistent with a scarce reserves system. So I think
thats part of the thinking; its a bit more resilient.
Question
One of your charts showed that ES balances were drifting down towards around $75 billion by
2028, but I guess, given the maturity of schedule and interbank activity, its still possible
for those reserves to dwindle down even further. Is the Bank targeting a number for ample reserves;
is it sort of between $20 billion and $50 billion, or is it more than that? What happens
when you get down to the scarce reserves situation again?
Christopher Kent
Weve called it an ample reserve system and I think thats a helpful name to
give it. But the other way of thinking about it is that its really a fixed price system to try
and keep control of the key cash rate. The fixed price system means that, if youre fixing the
price, youre just going to supply whatever is demanded. So we dont know when the banks
are going to say, Actually, weve had large balances in our accounts; we just didnt
need them for our daily payment needs; we didnt need them for our liquidity purposes. At
some point though, when they get low enough, theyll say, Ooh, now we might need some; I
might need some through next week; I might need some for tomorrow, and they come to our open
market operation. So thats the point at which we know were out of the excess, and
its also the point which stops us getting back to scarce. The banks … they might need
them sooner or they might need them later, when ES balances are lower, and you picked a number out of
the hat. We just dont know where that is. We could have some rough estimates. But the banks
will learn by doing as well. But the ample reserves, that full allotment option at a fixed price,
wont allow you to get to a scarce reserves system almost by definition.
Swati Pandey
Can I ask one question, Chris? We had inflation data last week. The monthly inflation number came in
at 3.4 per cent and has stayed there for three months; it was the third-straight month of
3.4 per cent. It has a 3 in front of you, so is that encouraging; or is the
fact that it has stayed at 3.4 per cent for three months, a sign of stickiness and of
concern?
Christopher Kent
Well, our forecasts embed in them this notion that weve had quite a sharp decline in inflation,
which is welcome, but then the rest of the distance to get to 2 and a half will take some time;
so I think its still broadly consistent with our forecasts. But theres uncertainty around
that, and persistence of inflation for various reasons is one risk. But weakness in demand could go
the other way, depending on how household consumption behaves from here, for example. So we think the
risks are fairly balanced around that central case, but the data flow of late doesnt cause me
to think that we are sort of off that central path.
Question
Youre talking about, under the ample reserves system, the ability of using the full allotment
system to sort of alleviate short-term scarcity, but you also mentioned the possibility that changing
frequency is needed if theres a greater demand for reserves at some point. I guess, possibly,
theres the possibility of adjusting the term of the repos development as well maybe. When those
changes need to be made, is there any concern that there will be, I guess, a signalling effect that
there are broader stresses present in the system, or do you sort of perceive that just running an
overall ample liquidity system will normalise access to the MO window enough that there wont be
a negative signalling effect? I guess, Im just thinking of some of the efforts that the Fed is
making to normalise discount window access over there and bring less of a stigma to that—less of an
issue in Australia anyway—but Im just curious on your thoughts.
Christopher Kent
Well, I think weve always managed to run a system where the banks have felt fairly comfortable
coming to open market operations back when they were daily under the scarce reserve system and then
under the full allotment that weve been running for a few years now, so I dont think
thats an issue. We dont know what the right frequency should be. It may be more than once
a week, because you dont know when the pressures might arise from time to time, either on the
demand or the supply side. They might come sort of just after the Wednesday that we normally run
these things, and then would you wait for another Wednesday? Probably not, depending on how extreme
those pressures were. You want private markets to work and move liquidity around as best as you can;
thats great. But if the system as a whole was under considerable pressure, you might just
schedule more frequent auctions. I dont think that will be a big deal. Again, that was one of
the key points of my speech. This is really about the plumbing; it doesnt signal anything about
financial conditions broadly. Indeed, if youre trying to avoid scheduling more frequent
auctions to avoid stresses, thats actually going to create the stresses that youre trying
to avoid. The better thing to do is just do what the market needs. But no one has needed to show up
daily, so its really a waste of everyones time at the moment with balances where they
are, both on the banks side and on our side. But if we need to change it, we can change it, and
we can change it in an instant; it would take not much more than a phone call and a quick
decision.
Question
Im just interested in whether youve got any comments about the US Treasury mandating
repos being cleared? Are there any thoughts about that in Australia or any readthrough to you?
Christopher Kent
So central clearing?
Question continued
Central clearing.
Christopher Kent
I know that its something that our staff ponder now and again, particularly in our payments
policy, which is responsible for central clearing facilities of substance; and, if we had one of
those, it would be of substance. But I dont have anything I can say at the moment.
Question
I know that were talking a lot about financial conditions and Im just interested in your
perspective on global financial conditions. Credit spreads are tight and equity markets are healthy.
Is this sort of helping or complicating the RBAs task and that of other central banks? I guess
that Im also mentioning the Bank of Japans decision as well and what effect that might
have on financial conditions looking forward.
Christopher Kent
There are definitely measures and weve talked about these including in our recent FSR—and there is some easing in some dimensions of financial conditions: strong equity prices and tight credit spreads. Theyre worth looking at and theyre worth thinking about. Markets can always correct when theyre priced quite richly. What does it mean for our financial conditions? Probably not much, and I dont think its complicating our decisions. While these are important dimensions of financial conditions, the much more critical ones are the cash rate, the three-month BBSW, the short end of the yield curve and the Aussie dollar. So whats happening in these markets is something that we want to think about, but I dont think its keeping us up at night. Theres not much to say about the Bank of Japan and their decision; it wasnt unexpected and I think markets are taking it in their stride. The Bank of Japan, in some ways, has disappointed markets because they were looking for more guidance and theyre not getting it, but theyll tell us when theyre ready. Thank you.