Transcript of Question & Answer Session Panel Participation at the WEAI Monetary Panel
David Frankel
Hello, everyone, and welcome to Melbourne Business School. Im David Frankel, the organiser of todays two panel discussions. Ill start by acknowledging the Wurundjeri people of the Kulin Nation, the traditional custodians of this land, as well as paying my respects to their elders past, present and emerging. Our first panel will focus on the monetary policy lessons that weve learned during the pandemic and its aftermath.
Our chair is Professor Chris Edmond, Professor of Economics at Melbourne University and a Fellow of the Econometric Society and of the Academy of the Social Sciences in Australia. In alphabetical order, our first panellist is Michele Bullock, Deputy Governor of the Reserve Bank of Australia. Also with us is Begona Dominguez, Professor of Economics at the University of Queensland; Ian Harper, Dean of Melbourne Business School and Member of the RBA Board of Governors; and Greg Kaplan, Professor of Economics at the University of Chicago. So, without any further ado, I give you Professor Chris Edmond.
Chris Edmond
Thank you, David, and thank you everyone for attending this panel. So the goal of the panel discussion today is about monetary policy and what we can learn from the pandemic. But I thought it would be useful to start with a kind of slightly backwards-looking focus, just kind of taking us back to those heady days of 2018 and 2019, when life was still perfect or close to it, and to ask — Im going to start with Ian — why was the RBA doing such a bad job of getting inflation into target in those heady days? So life was tranquil and yet the RBA was systematically undershooting the inflation target; what combination of factors do we think was causing that?
Ian Harper
A leading question; thank you, Chris. They were intriguing days. Ive been on the Bank Board since 2016 and, subject to being corrected by my colleague, we went through that period where we didnt move the rate for a very lengthy period of time. Notwithstanding, as Chris has said, that the inflation outcome was consistently below our target range, which was two to three per cent, on average, over the cycle, as says the target in the agreement with the government.
I think there were two factors going on, Chris, as I look back over that period myself. The first is that there was a great deal of uncertainty, and there still is in a way, as to what the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment was. We figured that it was somewhere close to where we were, but we werent absolutely certain where it was. And I think Id emphasise in this audience, Chris, that were talking about non-accelerating inflation. So we were concerned, given the history of inflation in this country, not knowing quite where that was in the fog, that if we were to stimulate the economy more than we were doing, there was a danger that unemployment would fall below that level, a level which we couldnt see, and then inflation wouldnt just go up but would become accelerating. With hindsight — with the benefit of hindsight —obviously, we were well above what we would now accept to be the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment, as a result of which it looks like we did a terrible job. When you look backwards, oftentimes of course you see things much more clearly than you do at the time. That was one factor. The second factor was that there was a significant build up in household debt, primarily as the result of rising house prices and people borrowing a lot of money to get into the housing market, and household debt, which is still very high, was growing quite rapidly. Not every central bank in the world also has a responsibility to look to financial stability, but the Reserve Bank of Australia does; so theres a monetary policy target to be looked at and there are concerns about financial stability. I would emphasise that the argument that Ive just put about the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment, I would argue, was the dominant argument or dominant reason, but financial stability is never far behind. And both of those things led us to be extremely cautious — with hindsight, excessively cautious — in how we set interest rates during that time. That would be my answer.
Chris Edmond
Michele, would you agree with that?
Michele Bullock
I wasnt on the Board at the time, but I would agree. I was actually in the financial stability part of the Bank at the time, and we did use to have a little bit of a discussion about that particular issue. And there were two camps in that: one was dont lower interest rates too much, because you might inflate debt more; the other side of the argument was just lower them as much as you like and use macroprudential tools to make sure that you clamp down on debt. But I think the dominant view — as I say, I wasnt on the Board — was just be a bit more cautious on the way down to protect against that financial stability risk.
Chris Edmond
Do you think its a problem that we can have a specific numerical understanding of the inflation target and whether the Bank is or isnt sort of delivering that inflation target but then, when you invoke financial stability, its much less clear what it means in practice to be delivering or not delivering financial stability? So already in this conversation theres been sort of several different potential indicators reference a household indebtedness and other things of that kind. So how should we think about that asymmetry of those potential objectives, putting aside just for the moment a broader discussion of whether it makes sense to have multiple objectives, given the limited number of instruments at hand? But just supposing one is to take financial stability seriously as an objective, how do you feel about that lack of specificity?
Michele Bullock
The way I would think about it is that — Ian expressed it well – the target remains inflation, and unemployment is also in there. Financial stability is a background consideration that I think we just need to take into account, so I dont think it matters that we dont have a really specific measure of financial stability. Its actually very difficult to explain what financial stability is. Its easier to explain what financial instability is than it is to explain what financial stability is, in my view. So, really, I think its a background consideration. But I wouldnt say we are using interest rates to dial up and back on financial stability. Its really about vulnerabilities building and, as weve seen in the Global Financial Crisis and weve seen a little bit recently, financial vulnerabilities build up and then there might be a shock that results in those vulnerabilities generating financial instability. But financial stability of itself, I dont think you can actually say Well, Ive dialled it up, or Ive dialled it down. That would be my response.
Chris Edmond
Greg, I just want to ask you: do you think then that the RBA should be sort of attempting to take financial stability more seriously? I guess a kind of response to that might be — and Im going to ask Greg to comment on this — that the difficulty with that line of argument is that it puts the financial stability as a consideration in this sort of catch-all position that can be invoked or not invoked. Its a little bit like the checklist approach to monetary policy back in the late 80s, where sometimes its a significant consideration; other times its taking a back seat to the sort of more mandated inflation and unemployment objectives. So, to a degree, I guess my question would be: should we be sort of thinking about ways to operationalise this so that were not in that position of kind of using it as an argument of convenience but, instead, have more of a sense of when to invoke it?
Greg Kaplan
I think its a great question and its a difficult one to grapple with. I would say that the starting point is to accept and embrace that monetary policy is a very, very narrow set of instruments. And, whether we like it or not, we can legislate all we like about what the Bank should do. But each time you change a policy setting, you have impacts on, we hope inflation, we hope employment, certainly on financial stability and certainly on distributional considerations as well. It would be wonderful if we had a tool that could pinpoint one of those.
Coming back to that question of Where was the RBA between 2016 and 2019? I think a lot of what was going on at that time was almost an over consideration of those core concepts that a lot of the criticisms that we saw were that the central bank was undershooting its inflation target. And now that seems to be — I think the one place we will agree is that we think that, if the central bank can do anything, it can impact inflation. We could talk about under what circumstances can that generate real effects on the economy? And one thing we saw then is that monetary policy settings were very loose at that time and the discussion was: should they be even looser? I was one of the people at the time saying, No, I dont think that they should be looser because, yes, we are understating a target but we can legislate all we want there are limits to what we could actually achieve.
Michele Bullock
It might be worth just adding too that undershooting the target and low wages growth and the idea that we might have overestimated the under-acceleration, this wasnt just an Australian issue. This was going on abroad as well. A lot of central banks were undershooting their targets. They were … underestimating the degree of slack in the labour market and, I think, as Ian mentioned, has been borne out now. We could have had the unemployment rate going down much further without putting a lot of pressure on wages, but we didnt know that at the time. And we werent the only ones; others were experiencing the same thing.
Chris Edmond
I just want to bring Begona in here, so Im going to cannibalise a question a little bit. So does that mean, Begona, perhaps that central banks around the world — it seems like there was something of a kind of common set of circumstances and perhaps a common conceptual framework in mind, and so it kind of leads one to wonder whether there was too much of a reliance on a kind of mechanistic relationship between inflation and/or wage growth and the level of unemployment. And so Im wondering whether you think that there was too much reliance on that sort of mode of thinking.
Ian Harper
A sort of stable Phillips curve.
Chris Edmond
Yes, is there a stable Phillips curve?
Begona Dominguez
Well, it seems theres not.
Greg Kaplan
Well, can I comment on that?
Chris Edmond
Yes, please.
Greg Kaplan
I think we need to call out the myth of the exploitable Phillips curve for what it is. It is a myth and I think — I guess well talk about this — one thing that were looking at right now is more and more evidence that such a thing doesnt exist. But if we go back to 2019, most of the criticisms of the RBA were coming from, I think, a perspective that: Hang on, if were undershooting our inflation target, that means were missing out on some candy to be had; we could have employment —the labour market could be doing even better than it already is. And I think that sort of thinking comes from an overreliance on this idea of an exploitable Phillips curve thats not really there in reality.
Chris Edmond
Im going to push back on that to say that I think — I mean, Im sure that there were people that had that view, but I think there are well-founded reasons to take inflation and/or price dispersion seriously as a source of welfare losses, even if you put aside the unemployment considerations. There are reasons to think there are welfare losses with undershooting the target, absent that sort of that labour-market side of things. But I take your point about that.
Greg Kaplan
Id push back on that. Its hard to argue — certainly, the costs of inflation that were seeing now at five per cent inflation over and above whatever they have on the direct real effects are there and different to being at two per cent. But to argue that theyre significantly different welfare losses from being at one per cent versus two per cent in that direction is sort of a hard argument to make without a Phillips curve in the background.
Ian Harper
Yes, especially if your concern is that you could accelerate it quickly, not just back to the target but out the other side.
Chris Edmond
Yes, like I said … its hard to get a little bit pregnant.
Ian Harper
Thats correct.
Begona Dominguez
The risk of inflation in Australia has been pretty low, but I dont think — in Europe and in other places they would see it a little bit more.
Chris Edmond
Alright. Well, this panel is supposed to be looking forward, so I want to spend a little bit of time sort of transitioning to looking forward, and thats to talk about monetary policy during the pandemic itself. I guess, in kind of crude terms. So Begona, with hindsight, to kind of take Ians favourite word at the moment, do we think that monetary policy was too expansionary during the critical phases of the pandemic itself, say, in 2020?
Begona Dominguez
I think so; I think so. From (inaudible) perspective, it probably was the right thing to do. We were hit by a very big shock, negative shock, and we didnt know when we would be recovering from it. But actually we recovered really quickly and it took us by surprising inflation started picking up in 2021, and I think at that point central banks responded a little bit too late, in my view. Most central banks around the world didnt respond until 2022, when we were seeing masses of inflation that we havent seen for 30 years. And, when we look at the RBA, the RBA was actually one of the last to respond to the increasing inflation. We didnt stop the bond purchasing program until February 2022, and the first hike in interest rates was in May, when inflation was already at five per cent.
And that brings me to two questions
should central banks have responded earlier, and by how much? And my view is that they should have responded a bit earlier, maybe six months. It was clear by the middle of 2021 that we were on our way up; measures of inflation — expectations of inflation were rising and becoming more skewed, so I think we should have responded maybe six months earlier or so. Now, by how much? I think maybe we could have increased the interest rates earlier. But offsetting all these shocks is probably undesirable, because it would have then taken the economy to a very big recession.
Chris Edmond
So, Michele, do you kind of agree that — Ill state the analysis maybe in a slightly different language — perhaps there was too much emphasis given to the adverse demand-side effects of the pandemic and not enough to thinking of this as essentially a supply-side phenomenon; and that, in light of it being essentially a supply-side phenomenon, the bounce back in the real economy could be quite quick, and that sort of stimulus measures that were put in place in early 2020 may then have been ex-post proved to be unnecessary.
Michele Bullock
Look, again with hindsight, I think what we underestimated was the power of fiscal policy and monetary policy, not just here but around the world, all pushing in one direction. This was unprecedented and I think people forget that we had shots of morgues in the streets in New York and Italy and, it was shocking stuff. We were worried about the potential for people to lose their jobs and never get them back again: basically, to end up with a really big structural unemployment problem. So I think what we did and I think what others did was —and the United States is a really good example — we completely threw everything at it and we relied on the ability that, with monetary policy, I think we could respond quickly. Theres a question about whether or not we responded quickly enough, so I think there was a bit of an underestimation of that.
To the points Begona was making about we should have responded earlier, I think youve got to remember too that we came out of our lockdowns and so on later than everyone else. So we were observing inflation happening overseas, and everyone was of the view transitory was the word of the day. Everyone was talking about its transitory, its supply chain issues to do with the pandemic, weve got Russias invasion of Ukraine on top of that. So we had these two massive supply shocks, and I think there was a sort of feeling that this was going to be transitory. What people hadnt taken into account, I think, as well as we could have, was that there was a big demand element to it, and were seeing that now, and thats why I think were all behind the eight ball. So, yes, in a sense, I think you could say that we threw too much at it, but we were in completely uncharted territory is what I would say.
Ian Harper
We also had a much larger labour market response here in Australia.
Weve had a much higher labour force participation rate and, therefore, much less action on wages than was occurring in the United States, for example.
So there was sort of no signs of inflation, either in the labour market or elsewhere, while we waited. And then, yeah, sure, it came around the corner.
Greg Kaplan
I have a couple of — I planned a couple of things for discussion.
Chris Edmond
Yes, yes — please.
Greg Kaplan
So I think the points about fiscal policy are really important. And supply side shock, yes, but we issued a tremendous amount of nominal liabilities, that if you just do the simplest, simplest monetarist arithmetic on it, will tell you that we should see something like a 15 to 20 per cent increase in the price level if nothing else was changing. Other things did change but just at a basic level. So thats sort of my apology for the RBA. Somehow, sort of out of central banks control, regardless of what one would have done, thats got to show up somewhere, right? Now Ill be less nice. I think the concern really is not so much the delayed reaction but the unconditional guidance that was given prior, and I think this ties into that discussion about Phillips curves and the critiques that were coming earlier on. My view is that its irresponsible to be giving unconditional guidance so far out into the future. And its even more, I think, unjustified then to hold onto that for so long, once the shock did hit. It is one thing to say that its not the central banks job to be giving unconditional forecasts, in the sense that they give — theres lots of things that might happen and it should be expected that, as those things unfold, we will respond to those in appropriate ways.
The language that was sequentially rolled out over that period that were talking about sort of unwound that in the publics perception that we went away from unconditional forecasts to actual heres exactly what were going to do. And I think that put the Bank in a difficult position relative to other countries. And what Michele said is absolutely right that things played out slower in Australia. But we printed the money at the same time, and I think there were a lot of reasons to expect that we would see exactly what weve seen right now.
Ian Harper
Do you want to comment on whether it was unconditional?
Michele Bullock
Well, I will comment, because I dont actually agree that it was unconditional. We were always conditioning it on the state, and there was a time bit: and we dont expect that we will reach that state until 2024. What I will accept — and weve said this in our review of forward guidance — was that the message got garbled and I think it got garbled for two reasons. One was that the media and people latched onto a date; they latched onto a date much more easily. And whats really interesting is that, even now, while were raising interest rates, they still want us to put a date on when were going to stop doing it. People are clamouring for a date; they just want one. So we should have resisted, I guess, a little bit more there. So that was one reason.
The second reason that I think we didnt get the message across really well is we talked around the sorts of things that we thought were going to be important and we got a little bit fixated on wages and — the Review makes this point as well — instead of focusing on saying We want to get inflation back in target, and leaving it at that, we actually went on to say: And well therefore be expecting this to happen to wages and this to happen on demand. So we muddied the communication, I think, and so we didnt do as well as we could have there. I would say, no, we didnt offer unconditional guidance at all, but I will do a mea culpa in terms of communication.
Ian Harper
Yes, your subsequent words in the publics perception are very important.
Greg Kaplan
It was perceived in that way. I mean, I think there was something interesting on wages as well, which Ill just add to that, which is we did have a big supply shock. What is a big supply shock? It is a reduction in real wages, which is the level of nominal wage growth relative to the level of price growth, and so we should have expected to see a slowdown in nominal wage growth relative to nominal price growth relative to what we were expecting previously. So I think thats yet another reason why that overemphasis on the slow growth in nominal wages was indicative of a stance on the demand side, but perhaps not.
Chris Edmond
I want to come back to this in a question of whether the RBA could have done a better job of kind of communicating some of the subtleties in, like, time-dependent versus state-dependent policies. So, Begona, I want to bring you back in here. One might think that its a little bit difficult to say to kind of like a lay audience that: You havent understood our complicated messaging. In some sense, it feels like the institution that is the locus of expertise in this space has, in some sense, an obligation I think, to provide education about what its language means; whereas I think what we see from the RBA is perhaps a little bit more — its communication tends to be a little bit more standoffish and not actually teaching the public what its language means. So do you think theres like a role — how would you imagine or how could an institution like a central bank educate the recipients of its communications about what that language means, without sort of undermining the message, as such.
Begona Dominguez
Thats a tough question. Also, I see what Michele is saying, because the journalists are going to try: No, I really want to know the date.
Chris Edmond
Right, Michele, exactly. But we dont want to take it for granted. Journalists are always going to want a simplification, but its the role of experts to guide people in forming their experience. So, if youre a criminal and you say, I want to get off, and your lawyer says, Well, youre not going to get off; this is the situation, its the job of the lawyer in that sense to provide realistic expectations and guidance as to the situation youre in and …
Begona Dominguez
Yes. You need to be able to kind of communicate the model that you have in your mind of how you are going to be implementing that policy. So, if you think that the right variable that you are going to be paying attention to is wage growth or whether it is unemployment or you want to have a look at vacancies, well, you dont want to muddy the waters, but you want to be able to say it in a way in which it makes that state contingent clear.
Chris Edmond
I think I was trying to ask a sort of similar question but with different language. So when do you think the RBA realised that their communication on this front was not working and that people were misunderstanding the policy? At what point was that clear to internal policymakers?
Michele Bullock
I think it was starting to become clear at the beginning of 2022, when we were …
Chris Edmond
As late as that?
Michele Bullock
I think it was, yes, yes. Ian might have a different view because I joined the Board sort of April 2022 and I thought it was starting to become clear then that there was a lot of emphasis being put on the date. Youve got to remember too that this was one part of a package of things that are done: lower the interest rate to 0.1 per cent; the yield curve target, which was the other thing that was challenging and which was also a sort of three-year target, which was the 2024 date. There was the TFF, which was also three-year funding. So all these things were sort of self-reinforcing. And I think part of the challenge of the whole thing was that, even though it was a state-based forward guidance, there were all these other things in place, which gave …
Ian Harper
The same date.
Michele Bullock
The same date on it.
Ian Harper
It reinforced it.
Michele Bullock
It reinforced it.
Chris Edmond
So I guess the question, in some sense — sorry, Greg; jump in, please.
Greg Kaplan
I just wanted to finish a thought. I had a question related around forward guidance and around this discussion, but —
Chris Edmond
Well, I guess my question was just going to be like: so suppose that we accept that at some point the bank sort of recognised that there was too much focus on the date and a misapprehension had developed for whatever reason about the meaning of that date in that communication. Suppose that one stipulated thats the case, is it obvious then that the right thing to do is not to try and correct that misapprehension, to try and provide some additional messaging around that and to kind of try and build up again a sense of education or understanding in the publics mind?
Michele Bullock
Well, I think …
Ian Harper
That happened, right?
Michele Bullock
Yes.
Ian Harper
I think Im not telling tales out of school here if I point out … Well put it this way, right? The Governor was asked by The 7.30 Report, which is a quite widely seen current affairs program on our public broadcaster here in this country, and there was significant debate at the Board as to whether or not the Governor should appear for two reasons: (1) because it was highly likely that the interviewer would be hostile and seek to twist the Governors words against the interests of the Bank. The other faction on the Board said, really, your argument, right: Heres an opportunity for you, the Governor, to now explain the subtleties of this to what is a sophisticated audience. This is the public broadcaster, so a lot of people who do think through the issues would watch this. And, in the end, the Governor decided to do it, and it turned out to be, I think, an exceptional performance on Philips part, if I may say so. So, Chris, the notion that the Bank sat there like the proverbial deer caught in the headlights, not wanting to do anything: thats false, right? Whether or not the Governors attempts in speeches and interviews were successful in allaying that impression, thats another matter.
Michele Bullock
And he was softening the language on the time base … through that period. So, we were trying to get the message across. But our traditional methods of communication used the financial press, for better or worse, and speeches and interpretations of those. Is there a way we can get more to the people that we want to get to without going through that layer, that filtering layer? I think its a really good question and, I think, something that well be thinking about. We have our speeches program and we have a school sort of university education sort of program. But what about this other group people that we really want to try and educate, how do we get to them? And Im not sure thats easy, but I think weve got to try and think about it.
Chris Edmond
Greg, you had another point that you were going to—
Greg Kaplan
Well, I was just wondering, given the audience here, whether it might be a good time to talk about what the role of this guidance is, in the first place. And, maybe to sort of kick off that discussion, I think there are, broadly speaking, two sorts of objectives, and it would be good to hear this from the Banks perspective. One is that one thing the Bank doesnt want to do is create unnecessary volatility in financial markets and destabilise the financial system, and providing guidance on what relative price is going to look like in those markets is important. To that extent, you dont want to be continually surprising market participants. And Ill put in that broad class as well what ended up being interpreted, which is youre going out to buy a house and, What can I expect in terms of my mortgage payments? because, at the end of the day, that is where the transmission is happening.
But theres sort of a second reason as well — which is less spoken about but I actually think is there without being spoken — which is, when interest rates got really low after 2008, banks around the world started turning to forward guidance as a stimulatory policy. And its not without coincidence, the time of these discussions that were having about the nature of the guidance, the nature of what those statements were and having to go on The 7.30 Report. If it was just about stability, we should be doing it and that would be happening all the time. But it happens at this period of really low rates, and whats going on there is this idea that its an additional source of stimulus. My own view and I think that of an objective outsider who came down from Mars and looked at the evidence on this …
Chris Edmond
Chicago is not Mars, Greg; anyway, go on.
Greg Kaplan
… the view, I think, of an objective outsider that came down from Mars—the same with the Phillips curve, by the way — is that, at best, theres no evidence either way that this has any effect and, at worst, maybe — at best nothing. So it would be good to get the thoughts on what do we think are the primary motivations, and how do we reconcile these two motivations for giving guidance in this way?
Chris Edmond
So can I just summarise that? So one motivation is stability and the other is using forward guidance as sort of a statement about the expected path of future short-term rates …
Greg Kaplan
Stimulus.
Chris Edmond
as stimulus through long-term rates.
Greg Kaplan
Well, we can talk about that. That may or may not be a transition mechanism, but the announcements of future short-term rates having a substantial effect on the economy.
Begona Dominguez
I think Id have a third one, which is the credibility of the central bank. If you follow with that, you are (inaudible) the reputation.
Ian Harper
Well, certainly, as I recall it, the idea was to try to encourage people to see through to the other side of what was a massive dislocation. And the expression I think that Philip Lowe, the Governor, used at the time was building a bridge to the other side. So encouraging people not to shut their wallets, not to shelve their plans but to keep spending, as a way of trying to prevent the state from having to fill that gap in other ways. That involved the Bank giving this type of guidance.
The alternative of saying nothing — and, again, this is another matter which is often discussed at the Board level, as you would expect — people dont interpret silence as conveying no information; on the contrary. We often discuss whether we should say anything at all and, if so, what we should say in order to try to encourage confidence as far as we can. Now, thats a tricky business, as you would appreciate. Just to swing across to stability for a moment here, Chris; and picking your point up, Greg—that is why the Treasurer of the Commonwealth, as advised by the Governor of the central bank, who happens to be the Chairman of the Council of Financial Regulators, made a comment the other day about the soundness of the Australian banking system. Now, thats forward guidance, brother. Thats exactly what that is Dont run on the Australian banks; you dont need to do that. Why not? Because theyre sound. Turn off the television and watching what youre seeing happening in Europe and the United States. Thats forward guidance. And why would the Treasurer do that? In the public interest.
Chris Edmond
But I think that highlights, like, a sense that the forward guidance of the RBA during this episode is distinct, which is the appearance of specific numerical aspects to that guidance. So, if the RBA had simply said in 2020, We are going to keep the cash rate low for an extended period of time; when circumstances start to change, when inflation starts to pick up or other signs of recovery start to pick up, then we are going to revisit our kind of commitment to…
Michele Bullock
And thats, in effect, really what we started off saying.
Chris Edmond
Yes.
Michele Bullock
And then the sort of clamouring kept coming, Well, how long is that? and our forecasts — everyone was at sea on forecasting by now, of course.
Ian Harper
A tsunami.
Michele Bullock
So, basically, what you said was exactly where we started, and then what crept in was: And we dont expect that will be until about 2024. That was how the whole thing played out and that was, I think, where we slipped. And I think we acknowledged in our review of forward guidance that we erred — we didnt do great on that. But, to Ians point about forward guidance, the Fed dot plots are all forward guidance. I mean, central banks around the world use forward guidance and have used forward guidance in the past.
Chris Edmond
Sure, of course.
Michele Bullock
And some of them use time base, so the Fed dot plots are all time based. So forward guidance is all around. Having said that, I think we dont feel that we would be heading back in a hurry to time based at any sort of time with forward guidance. I think our more usual practice is much more qualitative for conditions that we would want to see before we move interest rates. So I think we have learnt something from that episode that well take forward with us.
Chris Edmond
I want to start talking about our more recent experiences. But, before I do, I just want to touch on something that was brought up in passing, which was the yield curve control experiments. Begona, I was going to ask whether you think in the future the yield curve control is something that will still be on the table, or whether the end of that — so, essentially, the run at the end — is in some sense damning of the experience.
Begona Dominguez
Going back to what Greg said about forward guidance, I think actually there is more forward guidance in the real economy than the yield control. It seems to me that there is no clear evidence of what yield control has on the economy. At the end of the day, businesses and households in Australia had plenty of liquidity, so its not that they werent providing liquidity. It seems that it was mostly driven due to the three-year mortgage fixed term in Australia. I havent written up a model and evaluated how much of that has played into the economy, but Im not sure that we should start using these events.
Chris Edmond
Michele, Ill ask you then: how do you think about this in retrospect?
Michele Bullock
Well, in retrospect, I mean, again, weve done a review of this and it worked really well until it didnt.
Chris Edmond
Yes, exactly. Thats my concern, exactly. So then, all things considered …
Michele Bullock
So, all things considered, since then, I think — so we did that first.
Greg Kaplan
Can I just say, for the purpose of the audience, when you say it worked well, maybe you should just elaborate on what the objective was.
Michele Bullock
Okay. So the objective — well, as I said earlier, it was part of the package. So we had a very low interest rate, we had a Term Funding Facility that was extending cheap funding to financial institutions out for three years, and this was another way of getting the short end of the yield curve down at a low rate to, again, lower funding costs across that front end of the yield curve. And, as you highlighted, it actually did find its way into the economy because it found its way into all of those very low fixed-rate mortgages, which were coming back to. But, a lot of people, 40 per cent of loans, ended up being on these very low fixed-term mortgages, so people took advantage of them and it was really …
Begona Dominguez
In 2024.
Michele Bullock
Yes, thats right. Its not the US but, nevertheless, that was the purpose: to get that front end of the yield curve down. What I mean when I say that it was successful was, while it was credible, we didnt actually have to spend much money defending it, because everyone just believed us.
Chris Edmond
Well, thats a nature of fixed home rates.
Michele Bullock
So, you know, it was—
Begona Dominguez
But the effect on the balance sheet was huge.
Michele Bullock
The effect on the Banks balance sheet came from the bond purchase program. So we had the yield curve. The bond purchase program was rolled out subsequently when we thought we needed to get them down at the longer end –, so that was more aimed at the 10year sort of end – the longer end of the yield curve. And thats the one thats had the really big impact on the balance sheet; thats the $200 billion to $300 billion worth of bonds … and thats the one thats left us in negative equity. The purchases under the yield curve target were actually pretty small because, as I said, while it was credible, you didnt have to spend a lot of money defending it. And it was only towards the end — I think we called it in the review a disorderly exit — of the program that we were actually spending money, but the bulk of it was the bond purchase program. Now, would we do it again? I think our general view is that its not that flexible and its hard to get out of. And Japan has still got one by the way. The Japanese have still got a yield curve target on the 10year bond. So its not easy to get out of. So I think our feeling is that we would lean more towards — even though the financial risks are more with the bond purchase program, its more flexible because you can dial it up and you can dial it down a bit, youre not aiming at a particular yield, youre aiming at quantities. So I think that would be the way we would think about it into the future.
Chris Edmond
Well, I want to transition a little bit more to contemporary, so to speak: contemporary policy issues. Im going to start by picking up on this idea that any sort of inflation is transitory kind of coming from the supply side. Its a view that was prevailing sort of 12 to 18 months ago and certainly in certain circumstances. Im going to ask Ian: I think a lot of people outside of central banking circles, outside of macro sort of policy circles, maybe struggle to understand the role that monetary policy might have in dealing with supply shocks, lets call them that. So how should we think about the role of monetary policy in that circumstance; and are there other tools that we could be bringing or should be thinking about, if supply shocks are kind of dominant or playing a significant role in our current inflationary episode?
Ian Harper
Sure. Thanks, Chris. Well, those people would be right to struggle with that, thinking, So this is a supply side problem, so why are we trying to deal with that with a demand-side instrument? Well, the fact is, as the aggregate supply curve shifts off to the left or youve got a reduced aggregate supply for whatever reason, then youve got to make aggregate demand match that or else the outcome is inflationary. And so you end up dealing with a supply-side problem by managing aggregate demand in order to try to bring the two back together again. Now, this is against the backdrop of an environment in which aggregate demand had been deliberately expended to deal with what we thought was the opposite problem: a collapse of aggregate demand. So two things happened. Firstly, the aggregate demand didnt collapse as much as we thought, so the stimulus arguably was too much; and now youve got the aggregate supply curve shifting off to the left and doing its own work. So youve got two reasons to try to bring aggregate demand under control quickly, and thats precisely what central banks have done.
Chris Edmond
So should we be thinking — is there a role for other instruments? Greg, you might like to comment on this.
Greg Kaplan
So, maybe just to start telling about how I think about this, a supply shock is a reduction in real wages. If we think nominal wages cant fall, then the way that that might be realised is an increase in prices. That doesnt necessarily mean an increase in sustained inflation. I think part of the role of the central bank is the one that you were describing earlier, Ian, which is about coordinating expectations, about coordinating multiplicities, so you can have the bank-runs up. A bank run is a really good example of that. You can think of that as forward guidance; I think of that as the role of — as being a big player of coordinating expectations and coordinating beliefs. And the bank has a role to play in coordinating beliefs about what the future path of that required increase in prices is going to be and so that we dont fall into a trap of a wage/price spiral and end up somewhere where we have persistently more inflation than we need.
This idea of having to bring demand back
I must admit that I dont quite understand it. If theres a shock to the real side of the economy and it requires a fall in the real wage to bring us back to equilibrium, then that is the real equilibrium. If demand was high in the past because the government — the fiscal side really expanded, it doesnt really make sense to me that then the central bank should be pushing back on that. That seems to be a separate issue, but …
Michele Bullock
I was just going to say that I think theres a distinction here between ongoing inflation and a rise in the price level.
Chris Edmond
Yes.
Ian Harper
Correct.
Michele Bullock
What youre talking about is the need for the price level to adjust and what—
Greg Kaplan
Yeah, and what are the—
Michele Bullock
Thats right. And what Ian is talking about is: how do we make sure that its a price level adjustment and not ongoing inflation?
Ian Harper
Correct.
Michele Bullock
So Id sort of assert that its—
Ian Harper
Yes, exactly. So one thing youre keeping a weather eye on throughout this process, including now, is what the markets think the long-term expected inflation rate will be. And in our case, throughout this whole experience, the market has said that the long-term, 10year, expected rate of inflation in this country is 2½ per cent, right in the middle of the Banks range, throughout. And that, for me as a Board director, is one of the key charts thats presented every month; its to watch that like a hawk. Now, part of the demand response that looks like its a bit odd when youve got a supply side problem is to switch off one channel by which that long-term expectation could escape. By giving people the impression not just that you had monetary policy too loose for so long — and just flipping back to the earlier conversations; as you rightly remember, Greg — lots of people were saying to me at that time, even though interest rates were very low, You wouldnt dare put them lower; youre just putting more fuel on the fire that one day will come.
Greg Kaplan
You were just mentioning: what were the long-term inflation expectations at that time, when inflation was (inaudible)?
Ian Harper
Well, at one stage, this government — our government, could borrow for 30 years at less than 100 basis points and did, briefly. But they locked stuff in for 30 years. Bluntly, this university has borrowed for 30 years at less than 100 basis points. So a lot of people, not just mortgage holders, did very well out of that. But, throughout that process, the expected rate of inflation — if you asked people on the street, some of them would say exactly the same thing, but park that to one side; ask the markets, people have got money on it, and theyd say 2½ per cent. Now, thats not true in the United States. So, in the US, its still the case that the market thinks inflation is going to be higher than the central banks target. Thats not true in Australia, and part of the reason for that, I believe, is that we responded with demand-side management over against a supply-side problem to deal with that issue, well, amongst others.
Greg Kaplan
Id add that another part of that has got to do with our very different long-term fiscal position in Australia relative to the United States.
Ian Harper
Do you mean a structural deficit?
Greg Kaplan
Yes.
Chris Edmond
But a much smaller one, relative to the size of …
Greg Kaplan
Oh, I beg your pardon. Yes, yes, okay. Yes, okay, sure, sure, sure.
Ian Harper
So the chances of someone having to monetise it are much lower …
Greg Kaplan
Or a significant …
Michele Bullock
Monetise it.
Ian Harper
Yes, quite. I accept that.
Chris Edmond
So, lurking in the background here, I want to talk about the current pause in the increase in the cash rate and some of the circumstances around that. I guess, sort of a month ago, we had the failure of the Silicon Valley Bank and other kinds of financial market disturbances. So, I guess, lurking behind that pause and some of the related discussions of central banks around the world is the ongoing sort of tension between inflation control and financial stability concerns. So I guess Im going to ask you, Begona: is that something that we should be concerned about? In crude terms, is there a trade-off between financial stability concerns and inflation control? Well, I can put it even cruder: should the RBA have paused the increase in interest rates?
Begona Dominguez
For the RBA specifically? I would say no. Well, first of all, in general, I would say no, because central banks arent governed … countries have different instruments to deal with each of them. For the case of Australia specifically, we have APRA, and my understanding is that the standards of APRA are fairly strong in terms of capital requirements. And not only that; it seems that — I didnt know this, but it seems that Australia is the only country that has this interest …
Michele Bullock
Interest rate risk in the banking book (inaudible).
Begona Dominguez
Yes, which means that they require banks to hold an additional capital requirement to hedge against the risk of interest rates going up, which means that actually, for Australia, there is very little trade-off between the two objectives. Having said that, there is a caution to be made for the US and Europe because it seems that many commercial banks have been buying all those bonds and now they have many—
Ian Harper
As in Silicon Valley.
Begona Dominguez
… like you have read in the news, they have many losses, unrealised losses. And I read in the news that it seems like the … what is the name of the federal deposit?
Ian Harper
FDIC.
Michele Bullock
FDIC, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation.
Begona Dominguez
In February, they said that there was $620 billion in unrealised losses in the US. So its clear that, if you have this cycle of monetary policy tightening, that does want to bring some banks down. Why did they take so much risk, these banks? It seems like actually there may be some reasons for that. Maybe could be mismanagement, which seems to be the case for Silicon Valley. But it seems that there are also some reasons. I found this paper by Dan Ciuriak and—
that they found that it might be optimal for banks to actually take some of this risk to hedge against the deposit risk so that … But actually, I mean, there needs to be a bit of a balance there and then, since, some banks went over this. Having said that, still the US and Europe
they have ways of dealing with these situations through appropriate capital requirements, monetary in the banks and managing this risk. And, as long as they keep it managed, which is the case now, I think they should focus on bringing the inflation down and not …
Chris Edmond
Ill ask Michele the same question but in a slightly different way. So do you think that, absent the kind of Silicon Valley Bank and related events a month ago, the Bank would have paused?
Michele Bullock
Yes. Even before the problems with Silicon Valley Bank, we had already suggested that we were thinking about pausing because wed moved 350 basis points, 3.5 percentage points, in quick time. Normally, we dont. In fact, in other tightening cycles, we typically move a bit and then we stop and watch and then we move a bit more. But we had to get from emergency low levels, remove all of that stimulus, and get into restrictive territory. Now, I think what we observed was that we feel we are in restrictive territory because were starting to see signs on the housing market, consumption and these sorts of things, retail sales. Now, just stop for a minute and watch because we are — the Governor uses this term and hes got great terms, hasnt he — the narrow path. He likes the narrow path. So, to your point earlier, it would be ideal if we could get inflation down but keep as many of the gains on employment that we have managed to get through this period. So I would say, yes, that was always on the cards. The other point I would make is that, if you read the statements by — in fact, the Fed and the ECB continued to increase interest rates, even though this had happened and they both made the point that financial stability concerns can be managed with other instruments; they dont have to do it with interest rates. Having said that, what is likely happening over there, at the moment, is financial conditions more generally are tightening. People are running to sort of safer assets; the banks are pulling in their horns a little bit. So thats going to be a factor. Its not saying that the Fed is not increasing as quickly because of the financial stability concerns; its saying theyre taking into account the fact that financial conditions have tightened and, therefore, they have to maybe do a little bit less. So thats the perspective I would give on that.
The other point, not to labour on too much about it — but we did write about this in our recent Financial Stability Review, a little advertisement for you all if you havent read it, its a great read. We set out what we know about Silicon Valley Bank and the particular issues in those banks in the US. The US has bank failures on a regular basis. They have lots and lots of banks, thousands of them, and some of the smaller ones are failing all of the time.
Chris Edmond
Yes, but they dont resolve them through emergency FIDC measures …
Michele Bullock
No, because …
Ian Harper
(inaudible) the largest ones.
Michele Bullock
… but this one was a large one of the small ones. But it had —and the ones around it that were particularly at risk had — these particular characteristics: (1) was that they had a lot of bonds sitting with unrealised losses on their balance sheet.
Ian Harper
Unhedged.
Michele Bullock
Unhedged. (2) They had concentrated deposit bases, concentrated in two ways: large amounts of money by a small amount of people, and also the types of people; they were all tech people.
Ian Harper
It had a run.
Chris Edmond
Absolutely. It speeds that up.
Michele Bullock
And some of the feedback you get when we listen to regulators around the world talk about this; they say they had never seen a run so quick. It was basically a quarter of the deposits in that, because they were uninsured …
Chris Edmond
The size of it.
Michele Bullock
The size and the speed of the run had just never been seen before, so thats why the regulators had to step in.
Chris Edmond
They didnt have to stand outside in the cold.
Michele Bullock
Yes, so, sorry, Ive …
Chris Edmond
No, no, no. I think we can all understand that they are well-founded reasons why (1) a special authority was granted for the FDIC to intervene and then — in a situation where, at face value, they may not have. But Im more kind of interested in the issue of the interaction of these sorts of mechanisms with monetary policy and whether — you kind of gave a fairly direct statement that you think conditions are tightening in Australia and that …
Michele Bullock
No. I would say overseas they are tightening. Im sorry if you misinterpreted me.
Chris Edmond
Okay. Thats what I wanted to ask about. Go on.
Michele Bullock
No. In Australia we are actually not seeing signs of financial tightening here. The banks here: again, youve already highlighted the way that theyre very, very well regulated here. Interest rate risk in the banking book meant that they have to hold capital as the prices — if theyre not hedged. In fact, what they do is they do hedge, because they do know that they have to hold capital if theyre not hedged against these sorts of things. So theres no doubt that the banks are very solid here. Theres no sign that theres any tightening in financial conditions because people are worried about the banks or runs against banks. And, as yet, there doesnt seem to be Australian banks reacting in any way to tighten financial conditions either. So, no, I would say thats not an issue.
Chris Edmond
Im glad you clarified that because I was going to ask Greg this: do you think then it was correct to kind of pause in this most recent sort of decision, or whether we should have been continuing to tighten, given that inflation continues to be significantly in excess of target?
Greg Kaplan
Look, I think the more important question is: where are we going and how are we going to get there? My view is that the difference between 25 basis points now or in three months time over the sort of period that we think the central bank really can control inflation, is probably neither here nor there. Its more understanding what our members of the Board here are thinking about in terms of what theyre keeping their eye on. I think Ian nailed it on the head when he said, Were keeping our eye on what the lows those long-term inflation expectations are. And I feel quite comfortable as long as those are being kept under control because, at the end of the day, thats what we want to make sure: that these temporary shocks that weve been hit with dont translate into persistently higher inflation over time.
Chris Edmond
Thats fair enough, I think, at one level. But on another level, thats sort of like a rationale for not doing anything this month and then next month. Like, it can take — at what point does that argument sort of strain credulity, in the sense that — is it kind of like —
Greg Kaplan
(inaudible) some point between now and when it doesnt. I mean …
Chris Edmond
Well, let me put it this way. Exactly, thats very useful. So let me kind of make it a little more concrete. One might think, that once you see those measures of market inflation expectations start to move significantly to the point where you would then change the actions that you would otherwise have taken, that in some sense youre too late.
Greg Kaplan
You might be too late; maybe.
Chris Edmond
So then the question is: ex ante, what should we be doing? So just let me make this really concrete. Lets suppose that you were never going to see along the equilibrium path, if youll excuse the expression, a kind of a change in inflation expectations, right? So the question is: ex ante, what kinds of developments would lead you to change your monetary policy actions, supposing that, if you did things correctly in the rational expectations of equilibrium, you would never see those inflation expectations change?
Greg Kaplan
Well, Im just going to say the obvious, I think, which is that youre going to look at the signals that we see in the world that give us some confidence that the mechanisms by which we think we can impact inflation are actually starting to play out. In the model that you describe, you never see that; it doesnt happen; fortunately, we dont live in that model. But in that model, we also know ex ante exactly how much inflation we would see from a particular shock. So we saw the big issue in sort of nominal liabilities; we saw a temporary supply shock. In that model, we know exactly what to do. Fortunately, were not in that model because we dont see that, but we have a lot of things that we can be looking at and we want to be seeing turning points in there. So I suspect thats what goes on at the Board level and probably why they see in the communications that were starting to see some pressures on wages.
Chris Edmond
So you think that weve seen enough of a turning point. So well just junk all equilibrium talk and just say: so weve seen enough of a turning point, you think, that a pause is fully warranted.
Ian Harper
Well, Im not going to add to what the Deputy Governor said about that. The minutes havent even been released. But the minutes of the previous meeting, as she rightly pointed out, spoke about a pause as one of the scenarios or one of the recommendations that was put alongside another recommendation, which is that we go with another 25 basis points; and, as it turned out, the Board went for the 25 basis points. So the pause proposition had come up well before any bank failures. And in this discussion, well, I think you can read the minutes when theyre released.
Greg Kaplan
But, I mean, I think an important — obviously, Im not privy to the minutes, so I can …
Chris Edmond
You can speculate.
Greg Kaplan
I can speak freely and nothing I say has any weight to it. But it is the point that expectations dont move that fast. Now, its true that …
Chris Edmond
Well, they do.
Greg Kaplan
Until they do. But the idea that realised inflation is …
Chris Edmond
But this is the case of a problem or the fixed exchange rate problem: all of these things are—so we have very recent dramatic examples that they dont move until they do.
Greg Kaplan
Yes, in currency markets, yes …
Chris Edmond
And yield curve markets.
Greg Kaplan
And yield curve markets. Well, Im sure …
Ian Harper
Thats three years.
Greg Kaplan
But I mean in the trade for goods and labour, no. In fact, its the opposite; things take a really, really long time to (inaudible) were going to get a lot of warning there.
Michele Bullock
I mean, the point really is: yes, its comforting to see that long-term inflationary expectations are anchored. But I tend to agree that it would be too late if you saw them shoot up, its almost too late.
Ian Harper
Well, to the point, they stayed constant throughout the episode. So, if you thought, thats the only thing to worry about, you would neither have relaxed monetary policy nor tightened monetary policy; youd just sit there, which nobody is going to do.
Michele Bullock
So you are back to looking at — if you think we have an excess demand problem and were trying to wind it back, you end up looking for the signs that youre seeing it come through in demand, the sorts of things that were looking at. And were also looking at, obviously, inflation itself.
Greg Kaplan
Yes. And look, I mean, the Bank has moved — what was it — 375 basis points.
Michele Bullock
Its 350.
Greg Kaplan
Its moved 350 basis points. Thats a big movement. Ive been out on the record, saying that I dont think 25 basis-points movements here or there actually do anything …
Ian Harper
But they add up.
Greg Kaplan
They add up. thats exactly right. And I often get criticised, by people saying, Oh, so you dont think monetary policy has an effect at all? I didnt say that. I just said it doesnt really matter if were 25 here or a bit late or a bit later there. The reality is that its probably not going to matter. There are no people out in the street who its really going to make that much of a difference to. But it will add up and it will accumulate, and that has — so youre asking is the point — well, I dont know.
Begona Dominguez
The only thing is that, once you pause, when do you go up?
Michele Bullock
But the history …
Begona Dominguez
So they can do it.
Michele Bullock
It shows that thats exactly what we can (inaudible).
Ian Harper
Thats right. When the facts change, you change your mind.
Greg Kaplan
Pausing is more common than not pausing.
Michele Bullock
Well, pausing in the past has been more common. This one where weve done it at every single meeting is actually the exception.
Chris Edmond
Let me come in here. Its more the pause …
Greg Kaplan
Its almost like youre looking for an algorithm. I think his line of reasoning is in want of an algorithm. It says, Here are the inputs into our reaction function and they will spit out what we do, and I suspect thats going to be really difficult to articulate.
Chris Edmond
Ill put the point slightly differently. Its more like a pause relative to other major central banks. So thats, I think, like were seeing the dollar depreciate significantly and like we might …
Ian Harper
Not significantly.
Michele Bullock
No, we havent seen it. Its basically on a TWI …
Ian Harper
On a TWI basis, its rock solid.
Michele Bullock
Thats more important; its rock solid.
Ian Harper
Absolutely.
Michele Bullock
So, for whatever reason, the market path in Australia for official interest rates is lower than it is overseas. Now, partly thats reflective of wages increasing more sharply overseas, particularly in places like the UK, New Zealand and the US, so it might partly be reflecting that. But thats what were seeing in the markets and, as Ian said, theyre the people who are putting their money on it.
Chris Edmond
Well, Im going to switch gears a little bit to go to institutional questions more broadly understood. Weve already touched on, I think, the interactions between monetary and fiscal policy, so Im going to kind of advance a thesis statement and invite people to comment on it. So Im basically going to make the claim that monetary and fiscal policy cant be thought of as being functionally independent, in the sense that the path of fiscal policy matters for monetary policy and the path of monetary policy matters for fiscal policy. We have an institutional setting where its very difficult to comment in what Ill call a mature way about the interactions between monetary and fiscal policy without creating a lot of noise. It seems somehow undesirable that we cant talk in a kind of open way about the implications of the stance of monetary policy for fiscal policy, especially with issues of long-run fiscal policy; and we cant talk about the implications of fiscal policy for monetary policy, especially with issues of short-run monetary policy. So are there things that could be done to allow that conversation to take place in a more constructive way; or do you disagree with the premise? I guess that you can just say, I dont agree.
Michele Bullock
Im not sure I agree entirely with the premise. The way I would think about it is that, over (inaudible), fiscal policy needs to basically — it needs to go into deficit when its needed for purposes of supporting the economy. Then we need to be able to make that back, so obviously it needs to move with the cycle. And it has a structural element to it, and the government has to figure out ways to pay for the services that they want to offer to all of us Australians, and that involves them making hard choices about taxes and debt and those sorts of things.
Monetary policy is much more a cyclical thing, so I see it much more as … its difficult if fiscal policy is working completely at odds with monetary policy. You saw that in the UK, when the government tried to expand fiscal policy markedly while the Bank of England was trying to fight inflation; the markets did not react very well to that. So there is a sense in which fiscal policy and monetary policy need to be pulling together, but I do think that one is much more structural and the other one is much more cyclical.
Ian Harper
Having said that, theres a strong cyclical element, given the automatic stabilisers in fiscal policy and, at the moment, those automatic stabilisers are working very much in sync with monetary tightening.
Michele Bullock
Yes, they are.
Ian Harper
So the budget that the Treasurer will announce next month is likely to look a whole lot more in the black than people are expecting off the back of the result of cyclical tightening.
Chris Edmond
Let me just kind of push that. So, if the next budget is unexpectedly not as constrictive as currently expected — there is sort of surprise spending or surprise tax initiatives — then that is going to matter for the operations of monetary policy over the next year or the next …
Michele Bullock
To the extent it adds to demand in the economy and to the extent that weve got excess demand, then it does matter, yes.
Chris Edmond
And you wont be able to say a single thing about it.
Michele Bullock
No, thats not true. I think …
Ian Harper
The Governor has often …
Michele Bullock
He has often talked about that.
Ian Harper
Yes, to the extent of being criticised for making comments about …
Chris Edmond
Well, no, because then it was kind of construed in his much less direct terms; whereas it would be good if we had faster … Im thinking back to 2018-2019, and it would be good if we had faster wage growth in the public sector and things like that, which you can construe as relating to fiscal policy, broadly speaking, but I think you wouldnt narrowly (inaudible) the monetary-policy transmission mechanism and where we think wage growth comes — normal wage growth come from.
Ian Harper
Anyway, I was going to say one more thing about that. The other structural element — and, as youre aware, in comments that people have been making in advance of the Review of the Reserve Bank, thats yet to be released —people have said that its a problem for us that the Treasury Secretary is a member of the Board of the Bank. And I would say that, even if the Treasury Secretary is there, that officer is not there to represent the government; that officer is there — in this case his – his own capacity as an economist. But that doesnt mean that the Treasury Secretary cant inform the Board about thinking with respect to fiscal policy and does. So right in the room there, with one vote of nine, is a person whose day job is setting or at least advising the government on how fiscal policy should be set and, if we have questions about how that might feed into the decision the Board is currently discussing, theres the person right there.
Michele Bullock
I think everyone is very conscious of that. And, if you think back to when we were talking earlier about having inflation below target and the challenges of getting it up to target prior to the pandemic, one of the things that was going on at the same time as we were lowering interest rates was that the government …
Ian Harper
JobKeeper.
Michele Bullock
was tightening fiscal policy as well, so it was working sort of a little bit against it.
Chris Edmond
I agree, and thats the kind of episode thats then guiding my question, where I feel like commentary about the extent to which fiscal policy was unnecessarily contractionary in that episode was quite muted, I would say, relative to the fundamentals. I mean, you might say, Well, if you listened carefully to the right people in the right places, then you would hear it.
Greg Kaplan
But isnt that the idea? At the end of the day, central banks can set interest rates independently of whats happening with (inaudible).
Chris Edmond
So a fiscal instrument as opposed to policy.
Greg Kaplan
Yes. Fiscal policy can issue nominal liabilities and raise real surpluses or run real deficits …
Ian Harper
Yeah, like all independently of monetary policy.
Greg Kaplan
… independently of whats happening. The fact that there is an objective of the central bank that says, You have to target inflation, and the reality is, whether we like it or not, that the outcome of inflation is a result of the combination of both what the fiscal authority and monetary authority do …
Ian Harper
Are doing, yeah.
Greg Kaplan
… thats neither here nor there. The central bank can still comment on, Well, we have to target inflation and, given the fiscal environment, this is what were going to do. And theres nothing stopping the Treasury saying, Well, given what the RBA is doing, this is what were going to do. It turns out that the Stackelberg game normally works the other way, with the fiscal authority moving first and the central bank reacting to it. I dont think its legislated though, that it has to be that way.
Michele Bullock
No. But fiscal policy typically moves slightly slower than monetary policy.
Ian Harper
Thats the other thing.
Begona Dominguez
But also the rules of the game are different now. As you say, the RBA has a mandate while the fiscal authority doesnt have it. They are more prone to this question about choices. But I think there is a need for improving the coordination. Im glad to hear that there is this information going through. Im not sure there should be a representative of the Treasury in the Board.
Ian Harper
Ive represented the Treasury.
Begona Dominguez
I think thats mixing things. But, at the minimum, there is needed to have that information going on. Together with (inaudible), hes going to be presenting a paper tomorrow in which we see that the way central banks need to respond depends on what is their fiscal stance. But not only that; I think, to improve the coordination, we would need to have kind of some mandates also for fiscal policy to have some — we have the knowledge that fiscal and monetary policies are very different. Modellers agree that inflation is a bad thing, high inflation, all of us. But, if we start talking about what is the optimal size of the government, we might disagree very much. However, even if we disagree on that, we could agree on certain principles of efficiency or transparency and accountability, and all these things would help that coordination to work in a better way. Recently, Professor Eric Lippert from Virginia has been talking about the importance of transparency from fiscal policy. Like, we have been talking about forward guidance but also that kind of forward guidance to be also on the fiscal side so that that helps anchor expectations of fiscal policy, and that would help with your job and understand what is going to go (inaudible).
Michele Bullock
But theres sort of a little bit of that, isnt there, though, because when you do the budget, they do forecasts for it and they do …
Ian Harper
Yes, at the forward estimates.
Michele Bullock
that in forward estimates and, yes, there are some assumptions in there and so on. But they do a little bit of that.
Ian Harper
Theres more than there used to be.
Michele Bullock
Yes, so its moving that way.
Chris Edmond
I think weve had a good discussion and I cede the terrain, so to speak, but what Im going to do now is throw the floor open to questions from the audience. Weve got about half an hour left. So just put your hand up and well take questions as they come to Kevin.
Question
(inaudible) Its probably a quarter of a century since Ive really focused on monetary policy. But, reflecting on that, I think four words were very important or very common, and theyre related to this issue of the dates that things are going to happen, and there was long and varied in there (inaudible).
Michele Bullock
Yes.
Question
I wonder whether the thinking on that has changed. The second one was, Michele, you said were in the unknown. But, if I think back to the early 1970s (inaudible), do you think theres anything by virtue of that thats relevant now?
Michele Bullock
Long and variable lags: yes, its a term thats certainly back in fashion. And thats another reason for pausing, basically. You know, weve done — in 10 months, 11 months, weve done 3.5 percentage points and so, yes, were waiting now to see how long it takes the lags to come through. One of the things thats been interesting about this particular episode is that, as I said earlier, 40 per cent of people are on fixed rate mortgages, so its coming through slower into the cash flows of households than it has done in the past. So thats another reason why the lags might be slightly longer and more variable than they might otherwise have been, so another reason for the pause.
The lesson I would take away from the earlier 70s episodes is that you cannot let inflationary expectations get out of control, and I think thats all the more reason why — interest rates, actually, at 3½ per cent and the official cash rate, theyre still not that high relative to history. So I think weve just got to keep in mind that, yes, theyve gone up quickly and, yes, some people are hurting, but its not the whole population; there are other things going on here as well. And I think we just have to keep in mind — the lesson for me at least is – inflationary expectations need to be kept under control. So weve got to keep an eye on the long term, but weve got to make sure that we are observing whats going to bring aggregate demand back. So thats, for me, the lesson.
Greg Kaplan
Michele, can I add one that we can learn from the 70s?
Michele Bullock
Yes.
Greg Kaplan
So we raised interest rates by a lot more in the 70s. It was very, very clear that …
Ian Harper
Eventually.
Greg Kaplan
Eventually. But we got to a point where real rates were undoubtedly positive at all horizons …
Ian Harper
Okay, thats true.
Greg Kaplan
… but now we have to look up quite a long way to those inflation expectations to get a world of positive real rates. But I think weve got — I think theres something positive to take from the 70s in the Australian context, which is that there was also a lot of fiscal coordination at that point. If you look at what happened ex post, in terms of fiscal policy, its that, over the coming decades after that, there was return to surplus, and in the United States as well. Now, here, what you were talking about earlier, were in a much better position than a lot of other countries, and I think thats another argument for the pause. Its that, when we think about what were going to see on the fiscal side, that played a big role in the 70s, and were more likely to see that playing a role, I think, in Australia than in other countries. So I think you might have an easier job then.
Ian Harper
Yes. Just more on the 70s: weve been …
Kevin
You remember them!
Ian Harper
Yes, I do remember the 70s, Kevin, just like you.
Kevin
I just read about it.
Ian Harper
Weve been criticised — the Governors been criticised in talking about the risk of a prices/wages outbreak and of thinking in 1970s terms. In other words, people referring to the fact that, back then, there was a much higher degree of unionisation, much greater centralisation of wages fixing and, therefore, the chances — well the during the 1970s, we had actual indexation, as youll recall, where literally wages were indexed to prices. So it is true that, when the ACTU, our union peak body, and others make the point that thats all outdated thinking, it doesnt mean that there wont be a prices/wages spiral, but not for that reason. So weve learnt from that, I think, Kevin. Just to your point briefly there, Greg: of course, in the 1970s, the exchange rate wasnt floating …
Michele Bullock
Yes.
Ian Harper
… so we didnt really have an independent monetary policy. Thats one way to get fiscal monetary coordination: you just dont have an independent monetary policy.
Kevin
Thats a fair point.
Chris Edmond
There are a few questions here.
Question
(inaudible) In terms of (inaudible), talking in the post-pandemic—monetary policy in the post-pandemic — and thinking about the post-Global Financial Crisis as well — one thing thats completely different from, say, raising interest rates in May 1998 and by 300 basis points now is the (inaudible). And in terms of the political and (inaudible) implication of raising interest rates now, you have in the Bank — you know, the Feds are holding huge amounts of unrealised losses on their books and the impact of the C-note has just been sent back to the fiscal authorities. At some point, it gets noticed and its going to have, at least in the US, an impact in terms of monetary policy going forward. But now youve got these huge expansions of the balance sheets. So thoughts about that: relative to sort of what we learnt about dealing with inflation and handling inflation in the 1990s versus now, the big difference is the balance sheet.
Ian Harper
Well, the balance sheets are certainly different, but I can make the point in our case that the central banks balance sheet is mark to market. So we know exactly what the losses are and we know exactly how much were underwater with capital. And there was a discussion at the Board as to whether we should ask the government to recapitalise the Bank or whether we would just carry this loss —because, after all, it disappears into the public sector in the wider scheme of things —and work it off as the bonds mature. Because it is a mark-to-market loss, we will still lose, but the loss wont be as great as we approach the maturity date for these different bonds, it will come good. And the result of that conversation between the Bank and the Government was that, no, we would just carry it; it will be announced in the annual report; people all know about it. I dont think that thats made any difference to the effectiveness that the Bank has in terms of its monetary policy; its public information. The reason that its occurred is completely understood. The alternative would have been, as has happened once before, for the Government to recapitalise the Bank and to realise the loss on its own balance sheet straight up, but nobody thought that would make any difference really. And, in respect of the seigniorage point that you make, the Treasury is well aware that the Bank will not be paying dividends for the next, what, five years is it? And so they already know and have built that into their estimates that theyve got to find that additional money to keep their own accounts in order, because the Bank is not paying dividends for five years. So none of that is a secret.
Chris Edmond
I think we had a question here.
Question
Hi, Ed Burton, from the University of Virginia, and thanks for the shout-out to my colleague, Eric Lippert. The Federal Reserve — Im not that familiar with Australian banking or New Zealand banking — but the Federal Reserve system has been criticised quite a bit for its targeting policies. It was criticised for targeting rates, overnight rates, to be too low for a long period of time; and now theres a huge chorus from many directions that theyve stayed the course too long on targeting rates at higher levels. My question is — you always have to wonder what might have happened in the absence of some of these policies – and the question Id like to ask is: if, on March 15, 2022, the Federal Reserve had said — I can just imagine Jay Powell coming out and saying — Were announcing today that were no longer going to target overnight rates; were going to let them just go wherever they want but without changing the planned reduction in the Federal Reserve balance sheet, what then might have happened? It strikes me as unlikely that rates would have stayed low, with inflation clipping along at about a six per cent pace; so how much different would the pattern of rates been, had the Fed simply abandoned rate targeting in March of 2022?
Greg Kaplan
Can I just ask for clarification because Im not sure that I fully understood: and did what instead?
Michele Bullock
Yes.
Question
Continued the balance sheet reduction plan that they had announced in December; suppose theyd simply left that in place.
Ian Harper
Let the bonds mature and they dont buy any additional bonds back.
Michele Bullock
So they basically run down liquidity.
Greg Kaplan
They just run down liquidity.
Ian Harper
Exactly. They just left the balance sheet (inaudible).
Michele Bullock
Yes. I dont really know the answer to that question, I have to say. I mean, we do know that, in the past, post GFC, when they ran down their balance sheet, it did get to a point where the markets did, in fact, tighten quite significantly in the Taper Tantrum, for example. So I guess my question back to you is whether or not that would just result in a lot more volatility, which would be unhelpful, rather than the more stable process of saying, Well, were going to control the rate and well move it up in a controlled fashion rather than just running down the balance sheet and having volatility in the rates, which might be unhelpful.
Begona Dominguez
(inaudible) have a paper (inaudible) on how to manage the balance sheet. One thing that we learn is that it is good to do these things slowly to keep the economy stable. Im not sure about doing something quite different on — when you are in the middle of all those bad shocks happening in the economy. Im not sure its that good to add more volatility into it; I would be concerned with that. One thing that is different nowadays compared to the 70s is that actually we have central bankers that know much better how to do the job — I need to say this — so, to throw everything out of the window, I wouldnt do that in the middle of a crisis.
Question
I think the rates were moved 11 times or 10 times in a row, so my question is about the credibility of the Reserve Bank. Yes, there was a message that, until 2024, rates would not go up, and people made investment decisions on that. Another question is about countries, and the central bank would recall bonds as well of the foreign currency, especially with the USD bond sales going down and now they are investing in gold and gold prices are shooting up. So, in future, if there is another way around where Reserve Bank wants people to spend money and theyre lowering interest rates, why would people trust that that will stay in the foreseeable future and really spend money rather than paying off their mortgages?
Michele Bullock
Well, I think — and we concluded this in our Review of Forward Guidance — that, actually, our credibility, we think, did in fact suffer through this process, so I think youre right. But, if we were lowering rates in the future, I dont think wed be giving forward guidance in the same manner that we have given it in this emergency situation. So I think people would be responding based on their classic decisions about intertemporal substitution: do they want to save, do they want to — but we do know — one thing we do know is that Australians do like to save; they do like to sock money away into their offset and redraw accounts …
Ian Harper
Even when rates are going up.
Michele Bullock
even when rates are going up, and theyre still doing is. So, yes, I think the credibility issue is a good point.
Question
Given that were in a post-COVID world, Im curious about the learnings from that event. So I think we faced a pretty unique situation, where there was uneven impact on certain job sectors versus not; and my understanding of monetary policy is that thats relatively broad brush. And so, in the future now, in dealing with targeted interventions, do you have a better method of dealing with this, or are you coordinating with the Government better on fiscal policy, for example, or are there new methods still (inaudible)? Im just curious: whats been learnt in that situation?
Michele Bullock
Well, Ill start and, Ian, you might have a view. I mean, weve discussed this before. Weve got one — I mean, despite the fact that weve used these other policies, weve really got one instrument, and thats the interest rate. And, yes, its blunt. Thats the other word that comes up a lot: long and variable lags; and interest rate use is blunt. It affects different people differently. And what were hearing a lot about now is the people that its squeezing, which are the people that have mortgages; thats the one-third of the population. Theres two-thirds of the population that dont have mortgages, and quite a few of them are seeing the interest rates rise on their deposit accounts. So theres difference. So I guess I would say that heaven forbid that we ended up in a similar situation like this again. I think wed probably — and this, again, was one of the findings out of the Review – we insured really heavily for the downside risk. We threw everything at it because we were really worried about the downside risk. Maybe, in retrospect, going forward, we might want to do a little bit more thinking about what if were wrong on the upside and how bad could it be. So I think that would probably be the main learning. But, in terms of the interest rate, its what weve got, its blunt.
Swati, Bloomberg News
Michele, my question is to either you or Ian on whether there is any nervousness around the housing market, which is rising, and there are some commentators who are calling the trough in the market. So what kind of inflation will follow through from the housing market? We are seeing rents rising as well and continuing to go up. And a follow-through on that is whether youre putting hope over prudence in taking longer to bring down inflation.
Ian Harper
Ill have a go at half of that.
Michele Bullock
Do you want to have go at houses?
Ian Harper
No, no; you go.
Michele Bullock
Ill have a go at houses. So theres actually so many bits in that question. So the established housing market: yes, its fallen quite a bit since its peak, but then people forget it went up 20 per cent in the pandemic.
Ian Harper
Its still above where it was.
Michele Bullock
Its still above where it was …
Ian Harper
pre-pandemic.
Michele Bullock
pre-pandemic; thats right. Interestingly, initially it fell and then it rose very sharply. So its still above that and it has stabilised. One of the things we do know is that there are wealth effects. People do respond — consumption does respond when housing prices are — when housing prices are falling, its typically having an impact on the way people are thinking about their wealth and also their consumption. So, to the extent that it has stabilised, that might indicate that people have sort of stabilised at a lower level of consumption, but theyre not falling any further. So that might be one.
So were watching that because of the things that have been turning down. We talked about consumption and we talked about housing prices. The other thing in the established housing market, of course, is that there is quite a big pipeline to be run off from all of the stimulus that went into the housing market through fiscal programs and state government programs. But theres actually quite a big cliff coming housing approvals and starts and so on, six to nine months out, are not looking very good at all. So theres a few things in the established housing market. Some suggest that maybe things are stabilising; others are suggesting, no, theyre not.
The question about rents is a different one. Vacancy rates are really low; theyre at historically low levels in many places, and theyre below average in Sydney and Melbourne. We havent been building much high-density; all of the pandemic spending went into freestanding detached housing. The other thing that has happened is that household size has declined to historic lows. Through the pandemic, people didnt want to share anymore; they wanted to have a spare office in the house. So theres a few things going on there; and, on top of that, weve got immigration.
Ian Harper
Immigration, exactly.
Michele Bullock
Weve got strong immigration. So, yes, there is trouble brewing in rental accommodation, and that has implications for inflation because rental inflation is going to rise. So, if you put all those things together, Im not sure what sort of pudding you get. But its complicated and it means that we have to continue to watch whats going on in the housing market, because there are some things that are playing on the downside and there are other things that are actually going to be playing on the upside for inflation. So thats where Id say were at with that.
Ian Harper
Yes, thats right, yes.
Question
Hi my name is Sydney Libby, Im an undergraduate student at the University of Virginia, and I just want to thank you all for hosting this panel today; its been recently interesting to be a part of and listen to. So my question is regarding the long-term inflation expectations that you were talking about before and, admittedly, Im only familiar with the history of inflation expectations in the US. And, looking at the empirical data, really only in one instance — I believe, 1981 — the inflation expectations predicted what inflation did. For basically the entire history of tracking inflation expectations, there has been really no correlation between inflation expectations being able to predict what happens with inflation. Really, its been, unsurprisingly, that expectations are trailing the actual inflation pattern. So, going back to your mention of the importance of looking at inflation expectations before, I would love it if you could just elaborate more on that and why thats so important in your determinations of policy.
Ian Harper
Well, for me, it feeds into what I think the markets are thinking is likely to happen and the impact of that. Now, the fact that they may well be wrong ex post is — I take your point, but what matters is their ex-ante expectations and what theyre thinking now is likely to happen and how that feeds into the decisions that theyre making about buying and selling securities, which feeds into prices and interest rates. Thats the relevance of that.
If the markets start to — if those expectations become unanchored, then people are going to start changing their behaviour about how they can demand and buy and sell securities, let alone what they buy and sell in the markets, and that changes the response that we have to make at a policy level. So its really giving you a window on what people who are putting money on the table — what their guesses are about the future. And your valid point is that their guesses — it may just be a random walk; it may just be like throwing a coin or tossing a coin or throwing a die, when you look back at it, true. But what matters for us making policy is what we think they think
what they think were going to do, right? So its a window on their expectations of what they think were going to do, as a policymaker, and what the impact of thats likely to be over the long haul.
Question
So what they think is going to happen in the future is always wrong; it never correlates (indistinct).
Greg Kaplan
Yes. But the question is whether its systematically wrong.
Ian Harper
Yes. This is on average.
Greg Kaplan
So that would be a big problem. And, yes, I take your point; I think its a really good one. If its systematically the case that expectations undershoot or overshoot realised inflation, then you start to worry about if its just that theyre a mean zero …
Question
We (inaudible) take that forward, so theres no inflation. People dont expect inflation and then, once inflation starts to increase, thats when expectations — so they see whats happening and then they expect more inflation.
Greg Kaplan
Well, thats okay. What I would worry about is if I could predict inflation on the basis of inflation expectations.
Ian Harper
Yes.
Greg Kaplan
If that were the case, wed be in trouble; and, if that is the case, probably wed have to start looking at other data. I dont know whether or not it is. Its still consistent that thats not the case and they still follow; thats possible as well.
Begona Dominguez
There may be also many different forms of expectations of inflation. You just think about the standard (inaudible) model firms that are setting up prices and are going to be thinking about what is going to be the cost of the inputs that they need to buy to produce. That is going to affect how there are then going to be setting prices.
Ian Harper
So feedback on behaviour.
Greg Kaplan
Its a good point.
Question
Im going to ask a typical Australian question. Im from Monash University. So it is a common fact that both the economic condition of Australia and the physical policy were benefited by the commodity price boom during 2005 and during the pandemic crisis, and its likely that the commodity price will have to go down in the next one or two years and the Commonwealth Treasury is likely to have a fiscal consolidation. So my question is: will you worry that the current hike in interest rates will lead to a possible economic recession or a possible economic slowdown in Australia in the next two or three years; and how will the central bank respond to it?
Ian Harper
Because of the commodity price cycle?
Michele Bullock
Well, I think the question was that the current commodity price cycle is supporting the fiscal position of the Government; is that your point?
Question
Yes.
Michele Bullock
And, therefore, as that unwinds, then the fiscal position is going to basically wane and were going to end up sort of having — with the reverse of the boom from the commodity price, well end up with a recession from the commodity price.
Ian Harper
So monetary policy would have to be recalibrated.
Michele Bullock
Monetary policy would have to be recalibrated. The other thing that happens is the exchange rate can move and—
Ian Harper
And you get a natural hedge.
Michele Bullock
It does tend to — at the moment, commodity prices have risen, but our models suggest that the exchange rate is where it probably should be. In terms of commodity prices and interest differentials, it probably looks about right. But the other thing that could happen is that the exchange rate could fall if you ended up in that position.
Question
Thank you very much. Im from the University of Technology Sydney. My question is similar to the one that Chris asked to all of you, and its about the trade-off. Do you see any trade-off between the macro prudential policy and the expansion and contraction of different lending charges, in Australia particularly?
Michele Bullock
Trade-off. Im not sure Id use the word trade-off for macro prudential policy. The rise of macro prudential policy, I think, has been quite interesting over the last decade or so. Its always been used quite extensively in more developing countries to try and sort of control where lending is going and lending standards and so on. Its really only, I would say, over the last five years grown much traction in Australia. APRA started to dabble in this about five years ago. Theyve more recently sort of also added a very explicit one now; theyre going to have a countercyclical capital buffer, so theyre going to build it in now rather than just relying on lending standards.
But to your point, we talked earlier about the trade-offs between interest — well, interest rates and their potential impact on financial stability, and this is one way in which APRA has, in the last little while, tried to address some of those financial stability concerns. So we talked about pre-pandemic when inflation was low, we were trying to lower interest rates a bit further; we were trying to be a bit prudent. The other thing that was happening was APRA was trying to crack down a little bit on lending standards. So they were, in fact, moving into interest-only lending, for example, and saying, Well, well put limits on that. Higher LVR lending is another thing; in recent times, they focused on high debt-to-income ratio lending. So there is an increasing push in this. And I think youll see more of this from APRA because theyve got a framework now that theyre working on, and thats not done independently of the Bank.
Ian mentioned earlier the Council of Financial Regulators. In considering what role macro prudential policy might play in thinking about financial stability concerns, it gets discussed with the Bank and it gets discussed in the Council of Financial Regulators. So I wouldnt say its a trade-off; Id say its a part of the package of things that weve got available to manage the economy, and its getting more legs.
DAVID FRANKEL
I think weve got time for one more question. Im aware that theres someone there.
Chris Edmond
Theres someone over here? Okay. Right, well have two very quick questions.
Unknown
I agree with you; we definitely should end on time.
Question
This is a very quick question. Im from Uni SA. My question is about productivity. So there was a lot of talk previously about how, you know, the real wage is not increasing, whereas the nominal wage is increasing, and then whether the level of productivity is actually increasing in that place or not. So what are your thoughts about that one, in the context of the Australian situation post-pandemic times?
Michele Bullock
Well, Greg, I think — well, I could say that were not happy with it. Thats what I would say.
Greg Kaplan
Well, look, theres two ways to bring inflation down. Either you can lower the price of goods in terms of money, or you can raise the price of money in terms of goods; and higher productivity would be the best way out of this for everyone. So then we dont have to do anything and so that would be great.
Ian Harper
Thats right. Theres a thousand pages worth of proposals on the governments, on the Treasurys desk.
Greg Kaplan
Yes, exactly; at least.
DAVID FRANKEL
And over here.
Question
Ive got a very high, particular question. Im not a finance student. I was just listening to Michele about rent and talking about going down to an interest rate of 0.1 per cent. What stopped you from going to a negative interest rate?
Michele Bullock
Well, I actually wasnt on the Board at the time, and Ian might …
Ian Harper
I can give—
Michele Bullock
So thats my out.
Ian Harper
… you an answer to that.
Michele Bullock
But I would say — and correct me if Im wrong, Ian — that it was considered by the Board quite extensively, but it was felt that it wouldnt give you much. And, observing what had happened with negative interest rates in a number of European countries particularly, overseas, it potentially introduced some quite damaging impacts. So I think the feeling was that the Board decided that, really, it wasnt a path we wanted to necessarily go down. It was not ruled out completely; but it was really not a path we wanted to go down, given other experiences.
Ian Harper
Yes, a fair summary. Remember that the rate of interests on currency is zero, and the last thing we wanted was for people to run in favour of currency and out of the banking system. The banks, similarly, wouldnt or at least have shown great reluctance to offer negative interest rates on deposits and so, as interest rates go down and down, it narrowed bank margins. If you talk about your trade-off with financial stability, the last thing you want is for monetary policy running interest rates at such low levels that you start to compromise the income to the banks.
Greg Kaplan
Okay. Income to the banks is a good place to stop.
David Frankel
I want to thank everybody for coming. Also, please join me in thanking our esteemed panel of experts for sharing their wisdom with us today.
Applause—