Transcript of Question & Answer Session Channels of Transmission
Swati Pandey (Bloomberg)
Thank you, Chris. Ill start with a few questions and then Ill open the floor to questions, first from our guests and then from the media. So, Chris, with lags in transmission still being felt in the economy, does that mean no more rate hikes and that were at the peak now?
Christopher Kent
The interest rate question: its a good question. Im going to step back for a minute and
describe what I think are broadly three parts to the phase were in of raising rates. The first
part was a quick – a very quick – and strong recovery in demand following the pandemic.
That was accompanied by some pretty severe supply shocks, so that led to very high inflation –
demand well in excess of supply. So that was a story of taking away the very stimulatory monetary
policy settings and raising rates pretty quickly. Thats the first part. The second part then
followed when we were trying to get rates – a little bit more slowly – but still trying
to get rates into restrictive territory. In my speech, I tried to convey the fact that I think
were there. We know demand growth is slowing, inflation is falling, labour market conditions
are easing. Lags in policy, as youve said, mean there are still some further effects. And now I
think its possible, having done that, to be in this third phase, if you like, where we have an
opportunity to see how the economy and how the data is evolving. The Boards going to be very
much focused on those things I mentioned: global developments, trends in household spending,
whats happening in the labour market and, ultimately, the outlook; in other words, the forecast
for inflation and economic activity. And, as I said, theyve noted, after the most recent
meeting, some further rate rise might be needed. I think its important to recognise because
high inflation is such a problem for all Australians, its important to try and get inflation
back into the target in a reasonable timeframe. But weve made quite a bit also of the fact that
the Board is mindful of trying to retain as much of the employment growth as possible because
thats really critical for Australian welfare as well.
Swati Pandey (Bloomberg)
So another way in which economists have pointed out that you can still tighten monetary conditions is
if you do active quantitative tightening. There was widespread expectation that it would be discussed
in the October meeting, but we didnt see that in the statement. Do you have any update for
us?
Christopher Kent
Well, some update but not much. We dont have any current plans to sell bonds to pursue
whats called active QT. At the moment, its a passive QT strategy. So
weve had about $26 billion worth of the bonds weve bought mature to date –
theres quite a bit more still to come – and we said, back in May, that wed review
that approach from time to time. A couple of the things that were going to be thinking about
is, if we were to pursue a policy of selling bonds, wed want to do that in a way that
wasnt disruptive to the markets and wouldnt disrupt the AOFMs issuance activity, so
thats the first thing. But the Boards also conscious of the fact that a large portfolio
of shares still on the balance sheet implies interest rate risk that they need to think carefully
about. So those are a couple of the considerations. Its not about financial conditions though,
I think, particularly because, as I said, the long end of the curve is less relevant for Australia.
But we have an instrument – its called the cash rate – when youre
off the effective lower bound … you can move that around, as you need to, to tighten
financial conditions. The other thing and why maybe October was on peoples minds was the
rollĀ-off of the Term Funding Facility. So a big chunk of that, I think its about
$80 billion, was due at the end of September; so that got paid back, so thats great. That
went pretty smoothly. We didnt know that going into it. We didnt have massive concerns,
but you wanted to watch that carefully; that went pretty smoothly. There were some effects. You could
see it in various markets. Banks went out and issued a lot of bonds, but they were able to do that
pretty successfully. For a time, they were issuing a lot of bank bill swaps over that period, and
that pushed those rates higher for a time; theyve come back. So all pretty smoothly. But
theres another really large chunk coming June of next year – by the end of June –
another $108 billion. So nothing yet but when the Board feels the need to tell you that
weve had another look at it, reviewed the case –
Swati Pandey (Bloomberg)
So was it discussed in October, or was it not?
Christopher Kent
Youll have to wait for the minutes. I cant reveal what was discussed.
Swati Pandey
Fair enough. A global question: weve seen a big increase in US Treasury yields over the past
month and, in recent days, several Fed speakers have come out and said that it is tightening monetary
conditions for them and doing the work for the Fed. We have seen yields go up in Australia as well.
What are the implications here, and do you feel that is doing the job for Australia – for the
RBA as well?
Christopher Kent
Its obviously quite a focus for markets and central banks at the moment whats happening
in those important markets. There are two parts probably to my answer. I think the first thing is:
its worth thinking about whats causing those yields to go higher. There are a number of
factors. I dont think its a sign of problems in the US Treasury market in terms of the
way it functions. I think there are other things though: a broad rise in uncertainty about the
economy, about inflation. Some of that is geopolitical most recently but, broadly, supply shocks:
whats the path of inflation, how persistent is it going to be, whats the trajectory for
growth over the longer term? Theres considerable uncertainty about that. In the US
particularly, theres been a big rise in issuance as well, at the same time as the Feds letting
their portfolio of bonds roll off that they bought through QE. So thats having an effect. I
think, in Australia, some of those factors are at play but particularly not on debt, deficits and
issuance. Were in a fortunate circumstance where were running fiscal surpluses at the
moment. The other part of my answer is the long end of the yield curve, as Ive already
suggested, matters a lot less in Australia. Its not unimportant, but it just matters a lot
less. Most of the funding here is at the very short end of the curve. So those sorts of moves have a
lot less of an implication for us than they might in the US.
Question
I really, really loved that speech, Dr Kent. Im just wondering: I remember a few summits ago, I
think there was analysis on the relative impact of the total transmission mechanism on activity and
inflation in Australia compared to our peers, such as the US, Canada and the UK. Im just
wondering if that analysis still holds and whether youve re-evaluated that analysis, in light
of the research that you would have undertaken for todays speech.
Christopher Kent
If Im remembering correctly, I think the broad thrust of what we were trying to convey was,
even if the cash flow channel, which is what I was talking about today, is so obvious and quite
strong in Australia and happens with some immediacy, if you look back over past cycles of interest
rates going up and down, you dont see a lot of variation in the magnitude of those. If our
policy was so much more effective over all of those channels and we were being hit by the same sorts
of shocks, we wouldnt necessarily have to do as much. But we do, and that tells you the cash
flow channel is important here; others net less important than in other economies. I dont think
that sort of broad assessment has fundamentally changed, but Id also caution not trying to pin
these things down too tightly; because any time you run these models, if someone comes up with a
point estimate, theyre missing the point. They should be telling us how much uncertainty around
these things there is. So, more or less, similar sorts of effects, with slightly different timing and
different channels, which was the point of my presentation today. Thanks.
Question
Thanks very much for your speech, Dr Kent. Early on in this cycle, an argument from the RBA and the
market was that wage setting mechanisms in Australia were different to overseas, which was the reason
why we didnt have to go as early or as fast, in terms of hiking rates. It now appears that may
be somewhat changing, with the last couple of months of EBA data coming in, with agreement setting at
over four per cent, and obviously we had a very large award wage rise this year and last.
Obviously, some of the other private sector measures have been coming off a bit. But how are you
thinking about wages and, potentially, the risk that, when you combine them with very weak or zero
productivity growth, that creates upside risks for the inflation outlook, even if some of the other
factors are starting to fade as supply chains normalise?
Christopher Kent
My response would be that youre right: there are pockets of stronger wage growth, particularly of late, that are obvious and quite prominent. But when you step back and you take a broader look at the whole market, some of those things are applying to small segments of various parts of the market. The broad picture, I think, is one where weve had a higher nominal wage growth than in the past, of late, but it doesnt seem to be pushing higher. Thats also the message were getting through liaison. So it doesnt mean youre not going to be able to find examples where that does seem to be the case, but the broad aggregates at the moment are saying thats not happening. But as weve pointed out before, thats fine; the current nominal wage growth doesnt put at risk achieving the inflation target, so long as we can get a turnaround in productivity. So our forecasts are still predicated on a pick-up in productivity, which has been weak and even declining on some measures. I think there are reasonable prospects for that to happen, but thats just another thing the Boards going to be looking at closely. The challenge, of course, is pinning that down in real time. The estimates come late; theyre highly variable. A good way to think about what matters is, ultimately, what matters for inflation. So looking at inflation gives you a lot of timely information on all sorts of cost pressures, not just wages.
Question
Thanks, Chris. You mentioned several transmission channels. Just for one of them, credit channel, Im just wondering: whats your observation and take for the recent development of private credit business and its impact on this, and especially its impact on the monetary policy?
Christopher Kent
Im sorry; I didnt quite catch what – the impact of which?
Question
Yes, so private credit, because banks – obviously, they are, I mean, not lending as much as
before, but many companies are lending directly to individuals, high-net-worth individuals and
businesses, and Im just wondering whats your observation and your take on this and, of
course, its impact on monetary policies. Thank you.
Christopher Kent
So, if I understand that question correctly, its about new forms of credit and finance that are
not necessarily traditional channels through the banks. The biggest non-bank source of credit is
often through non-bank financial institutions that raise a lot of funds by securitisation, so they
bundle loans together. I know thats not necessarily what youre talking about, but
theyre kind of the next biggest in town. They generally, compared to during the pandemic, have
had a higher cost of funding through that source – coming off a bit more recently, but a higher
cost than the banks. So their funding costs have been going up more than banks and so their extension
of credit has been a bit less. But even that source – and I know youre talking about
something different again – that source only accounts for about four or five per cent of
total credit. So the big story is still whats happening on the banking side of things. And,
when you look at credit, whether its to businesses or households, its come off.
Households sitting around a four per cent annualised rate and doesnt look like it will
push higher; business credit has come right down as well. Thats not just the credit channel,
but thats the sort of thing youd expect from the credit channel. So I think thats
monetary policy having an effect, even if there might be some other marginal sources which are
growing.
Peter Hannam (The Guardian)
Thank you for the speech, Dr Kent. Could you describe a little bit about the modelling on, say, the
asset channel effect of higher interest rates, given that house prices havent declined perhaps
as you might have expected and theyre picking up again with higher population growth. What is
that, I guess, factor in your estimation where interest rates are going to go? Could we expect rising
house prices to shift the odds for, say, another interest rate rise? How much more, if you like,
would house prices have to move before your modelling changes?
Christopher Kent
I noted in my speech youd normally expect house prices to have come off, and thats what
they did through last year, if the biggest effect operating on them is just interest rates. But there
are these other factors. Its hard to deny that a rise in house prices is stronger wealth than
otherwise. I think the thing that makes me a bit cautious about saying, Thats going to be
problematic and drive consumption, is there are so many other features weighing on consumption
at the moment. And, quite often, its hard to really identify this wealth channel accurately and
consistently over time because things are always a bit different. And the thing thats a bit
different this time, from previous increases in house prices, is interest rates are rising, the
credit channel is still at play. Turnover is still fairly low, it hasnt really shot up, and
thats consistent with the point I was making about: if you were a borrower going out, compared
to before when we raised the cash rate, the banks, which are the largest source of credit, will give
you 30 per cent less, on average, than in the past. So its hard to see, in that
environment, it being a major concern, but its still something wed be watching at
throwing into the mix and influencing the outlook for activity and inflation.
Question
Good afternoon. Thanks for your talk, Chris. The market has seen the Reserve Bank being on hold for
the past four months and is wondering if this is the peak or maybe the Reserve Bank will go further.
The expectation is that the Q3 CPI – I think its late October – is something
that could make or break a hike in November. Youve said that the outlook for inflation is the
single most important thing for the outlook for policy. Is the CPI going to be enough to shift the
Bank given the weak household sector, given the weak China and the weak Europe? Might the CPI be
important enough to make or break? Is it a little surprise you need on the upside or a big surprise,
to get the Bank moving again? Thank you.
Christopher Kent
Well, youve asked all the good questions the Board need to be asking themselves come November.
The CPI is important; its the thing were targeting. As I suggested earlier, it gives you
quite a lot of information on a timely basis compared to things like unit labour costs, which come
with a lag, measured not particularly well – its not the fault of the ABS; its just
the nature of the beast – and subject to lots of revision. So its absolutely an important
thing to be looking at. But its not the only thing were going to be looking at. We have
to put that together with the pictures of whats happening in the labour market and, as
youve suggested, whats happening to the household sector. Housing spending is such a
large part of total spending in the economy, and that seems particularly weak at the moment. The
labour market, thankfully, is easing, and a lot of that is vacancies coming off. So I dont like
to suggest theres just one thing and theres one threshold and its a done deal.
Its much more putting the whole picture together and well look at all of our forecasts.
But thats an important variable. And thats why, I think, if you ask market economists,
which we do and others do … theyre focused on November, partly for that reason, as an
important meeting, the OIS curve is giving some probability to that but not much and its
pricing a bit further out.
Question
Thank you, Chris. I wanted to ask about the interaction of monetary and fiscal policy. Of course,
last year, the federal government ran a big surplus, the first in 15 years, but going back to
deficit this year; Queensland is doing the same thing. If I look at the fiscal stance of federal and
state together and the change from last year to this year, at least on my estimate, its about
two per cent of GDP in stimulus, the biggest increase in fiscal stimulus outside of the GFC and
COVID in 20 years. You note in your chart also that dwelling investment is very weak. The
governments got a target of 1.2 million houses in the next five years; thats going
to require the level of dwelling completions to increase by 25 per cent from current levels
and stay there for 20 quarters. Is fiscal policy at odds with monetary policy, and is that
putting more work on the RBA?
Christopher Kent
Our forecasts already try and embed as much of that as we can, both the federal and the state. I
think its great that youve mentioned the state governments matter as well. And the states
are also thinking about their investment programs and the fact that theyre costing quite a bit
– thats an environment of high inflation – and what they might do to slow some of
these. So youll always be thinking actively about monetary policy and fiscal policy, but we try
and take that stance as given. And I think its important to recognise as well, at least at a
federal level, things like the automatic stabilisers are at play here, and you could see that in my
graph of household disposable income. The tax take is something weighing on household disposable
income. I think thats an appropriate sort of approach. Thats part of the reason why in a
strong environment of inflation but also employment growth, very strong employment growth,
thats a natural and appropriate thing to happen. So, we try and take all of those things into
account as best we can, and we keep an eye on changes there. I think thats already in our
outlook: for inflation to come back gradually. But things are heading in the right sort of direction.
The labour market is easing and consumption growth is pretty weak.
Ross Greenwood (Sky News)
I just want to ask about the target to bring inflation back into the desired band by late-2025. In
the speech, you seemed to indicate that, there could be other issues of urgency which could even
change that glide path, in terms of trying to maintain as full employment as you possibly can. Can
you just explain what things could knock you off that glide path, in terms of trying to maintain the
jobs while bringing down inflation to that target band by the end of 2025?
Christopher Kent
I would step back from it all and say we often talk about our central forecasts. I like to think in a
world where its very hard to forecast; its even hard to know where youre currently
at right now. I think weve got a reasonable handle on where we are right now but then, by the
time you go out that far, theres a lot of uncertainty. So its really a matter of just
keeping an eye on things as we go. I think, in the past, weve made it pretty clear we would be
not wanting to see inflation take much longer. But youd have to add up a lot of different
factors that would all move in one direction, its possible that that was to happen, for the
Board to want to react. Theyve said they may need to raise interest rates in the future to
bring inflation down. I think thats a reflection of the fact that we wouldnt want it to
be much slower. You can tell all sorts of stories as to why that would not be the case. One concern
would just be inflation expectations resetting if there were some further significant upward shocks.
You can tell whatever stories you like about what might cause those. But at the same time, household
demand, as it was suggested, is pretty weak, and that could be the sort of thing, that weakness, that
turns the labour market a bit faster; that eases conditions there and brings inflation down faster.
So there are lots of possibilities, but I think I would be the first, and thats what I used to
do when I was (the Banks) chief economist, to emphasise just how wide those bands of
uncertainty are, and it means its a constant job of just looking, monitoring, trying to absorb
things. But its not one thing that will do it; its a mix of things that would set you off
on one course either way.
Question
Thank you so much for your presentation. Weve seen oil rises spiking again and geopolitical
risks arising. How concerned are you that were going to see inflation spike upwards again at
the same point as were seeing weakening demand in consumption?
Christopher Kent
Well, those are kind of alluding to some of the things that I think Ross was hinting at. But if you put those two together, the effect – it could be offsetting. Higher oil price is an important element but not the only element that goes into input costs and inflation, but weaker demand kind of works the other way. So I think it would be depending on the balance of those sorts of things. Remember, commodity prices generally: if theyre high, including oil prices and gas, which is linked to that, thats generally positive for our export prices. So, yes, not good for the household sector but good for the economy overall, in terms of our income. So you have to think about all of that together. But you kind of gave me an out there. If its just the oil price by itself, well, thats problematic, if its persistent, if it leaks into household inflation expectations and businesses. But then, if demand is weaker, generally thats going the other way. So youd have to weigh all those up, and thats the sort of thing the Board does every time it sits down and considers the forecasts. Well be doing that soon. Thank you.